The Supreme Position of the U.S. Dollar in New Financial Innovations and Instruments

Yves here. This part two of a four-part series summarizing a new paper by by Junji Tokunaga and Gerald Epstein of the Political Economy Research Institute (University of Massachusetts-Amherst) working paper “The Endogenous Finance of Global Dollar-Based Financial Fragility in the 2000s: A Minskian Approach,” by Junji Tokunaga and Gerald Epstein, Part one is here.

One issue I wish this post made clearer was the specific mechanism by which financial “innovation” induced foreign investors to buy US asset-backed securities such as subprime mortgage-backed securities and CDOs, prior to the crisis. The big flow was from European investors. One big driver was regulatory arbitrage. Basel II allowed for AAA-rated assets held by banks to get a 20% risk weighting, and if they were hedged by an AAA counterparty, the risk weight dropped to zero. So if you could hedge an AAA asset for less than your spread over your cost of funding, Eurobank risk weighting systems treated the resulting trade as “freeing up capital” and discounted future value of the cash flows over the life of the transaction. For traders, this was free money. As Andrew Ditter wrote in 2010:

The links between the demand for CDOs and the “negative basis trade” that was arguably a widespread form of bonus fraud. (When a AAA instrument was insured by an AAA guarantor, internal reports typically treated it as if all the expected income in future years was discounted to the present. As we know now, in the overwhelming majority of cases, bonuses were paid on income that was never earned. This mechanism was THE reason many banks would up holding so much AAA CDO inventory – it was more lucrative for the traders to retain and “hedge” it than sell it.)

Many of the Eurobanks, particularly Deutsche Bank, SocGen and UBS, were active participants in the CDO business. UBS was so keen to play the negative basis trade that they bought other banks’ CDOs. Another big universe of RMBS/CDO investors were the German Landesbanken. They were dumb money and preferred stuffees. Virtually all are in liquidation.

By Junji Tokunaga, Associate Professor in the Department of Economics and Management, Wako University, Tokyo and Gerald Epstein, Professor in the Department of Economics, University of Massachusetts-Amherst, and Co-Director of the Political Economy Research Institute (PERI). Originally published at Triple Crisis

Importantly, the supreme position of U.S. dollar in new financial innovations and instruments contributed to halting the declining trend of the dollar as a debt-financing currency and reversed the falling role of the dollar in the 2000s.

First of all, an unprecedented increase in U.S. dollar-denominated asset-backed security (ABS) issuance contributed to the revival of the dollar as a debt-financing currency in the 2000s. Currency shares in ABS and non-convertible bond issuance is provided in Figure 7. The share of U.S. dollar in ABS issuance rose from around 65 percent in 1999 to 75-80 percent on the eve of the financial crisis (as shown in Panel B), while the share of euro increased gradually from around 15% to in 1999 to about 20 percent, respectively (as demonstrated in Panel A).

Tokunaga-Epstein-Figure-71-e1390970166246

ECB [2011] explains some factors underlying the decision on the currency denomination of ABS issuance as follows: Firstly, the origin of the underlying collateral, as well as investors’ preferences, seems to be an important factor in the decision on the currency denomination of ABS issuance. In fact, substantial amounts of collateral are located in the U.S. Secondly, the development of new financial innovations and instruments plays an important role in influencing a currency’s prominence in global financial markets. In particular, the securitization function can transform risky, long-term loans (subprime mortgage in the U.S., for example) into seemingly credit-risk free, dollar-denominated long-term debt securities such as ABS.

In addition, the dominant position of the dollar in credit default swaps (CDSs) is thought to support the prominence of U.S. dollar-denominated ABS issues. A CDS is a swap contract in which the buyer of the CDS protection makes a series of payments to the seller of it, and receives a payoff if a credit instrument goes into default. CDSs function as a hedging credit risk associated with the underlying assets. LCFIs bought large amounts of CDSs on ABS and CDO written by insurance companies.[31] Table 1 demonstrates currency breakdown of credit derivatives from May 1 to July, 2010. While the percent of the dollar in total transactions amounted to 63%, its share reached 57% in total notional size.

Tokunaga-Epstein-Table-11-e1390970214713

Secondly, the rapid growth of U.S. dollar-denominated safe, short-term and liquid assets facilitated the revival of the dollar as debt-financing currency in the 2000s. Table 2 reports total asset-backed commercial paper (ABCP) outstanding by the location of the sponsor and the funding currency as of January 2007. In total, $714 billion out of $969 billion, or 73.7 percent, was issued in the dollar. Notably, most European banks financed their off-balance vehicles by issuing ABCP denominated in dollars rather than in euro.

Tokunaga-Epstein-Table-21-e1390970256409

Also, there are no official data on the currency denomination in the repo market, which is at the center of the globally integrated wholesale funding process. Table 3 presents liabilities and equity of the domestic economy and amounts held by rest of world as of June 2007. Foreign holdings of Treasuries bonds made up the largest percentage of the amount outstanding (45%), the share of Agency bonds, corporate bonds (non asset-backed), and corporate ABS+ABCP (asset-backed commercial paper) reached 21%, 25%, and 22%, respectively, which were a higher share than total foreign holdings (13%). U.S. treasuries have played the role of “universally accepted collateral,” that is, the asset most widely accepted as collateral in repo markets.[32] Taking the higher share of foreigners holding U.S. private debt securities into account, a broad range of private debt instruments, whose underlying assets are located in the U.S., has been also used for “universally accepted collateral” in the global repo market in the 2000s. It is, therefore, likely that the dollar has played the dominant role as collateral assets in the global repo market.

In summary, most of both long-term (ABS) and short-term debt instruments (ABCP and repos) created by LCFIs in the global shadow banking system were denominated in U.S. dollars. This resulted in the revival of the dollar as a debt-financing currency in the 2000s, despite the persistent decline in currency asymmetry since the second half of the 1980’s. Importantly, the revival of the dollar as a debt-financing currency underpinned by the dominant role of U.S. dollar in new financial innovation and instruments, supported the endogenous finance of the global dollar in the 2000s.

Notes

[31] IMF [2011a] presents a case study that global systemically important financial institutions (G-SIFIs) bought large amounts of credit default swaps (CDSs) on largely subprime mortgage collateralized debt obligations (CDOs) written by AIG Financial Products (AIGFP), which was a London branch of a French incorporated subsidiary (pp.8-13).

[32] Schinasi et al. [2001], pp.4-5.
– See more at: http://triplecrisis.com/global-dollar-based-financial-fragility-in-the-2000s-part-2/#sthash.6pSLYEpf.dpuf

Print Friendly, PDF & Email

One comment

  1. financial matters

    Thanks Yves for the succinct explanation on how bank bonuses were paid from this AAA securitization fiasco.

    I think one of the important parts of the article is “the repo market, which is at the center of the globally integrated wholesale funding process.”

    I think this is a central point as this is where people’s money market funds gets fed into the investment bank derivative business as they (money market funds) search for higher yield mainly to avoid ‘breaking the buck’.

    Also “Foreign holdings of Treasuries bonds made up the largest percentage of the amount outstanding (45%), the share of Agency bonds, corporate bonds (non asset-backed), and corporate ABS+ABCP (asset-backed commercial paper) reached 21%, 25%, and 22%, respectively, which were a higher share than total foreign holdings (13%). U.S. treasuries have played the role of “universally accepted collateral,” that is, the asset most widely accepted as collateral in repo markets.”

    It would make sense that Treasuries being the reserve currency would be a large part of this market. I think the mention of commercial paper is important here.

    This money market/commercial paper foundation that provides for this ‘wholesale funding process’ is being misused to generate financial instruments rather than true productivity and the Fed had to go to great lengths to stabilize it..

    The Fed set up a few facilities to address this ‘commercial paper’ problem..

    “4.4.2 CPFF

    Like AMLF, the Commercial Paper Funding Facility (CPFF) was also directed toward credit markets and had nearly the same operational duration, running from October 2008 to February 2010 with 1,159 transactions. Unlike AMLF, this facility was designed to support the commercial paper (CP) market rather than MMMFs. Because the CP market saw its funding move into safer securities after Lehman’s collapse—primarily government treasuries—issuers faced rollover risk and a plummeting issuance rate.64 The CP market would shrink by as much as $300 billion by the end of October 2008 (a month after Lehman’s bankruptcy) with 70 percent of this due to reductions in the issuance of financial CP and 20 percent from ABCP reductions.65 A new source of funding was required to drive new issuances of CP. Because purchasing CP by issuers was outside the operating framework of the Fed, the creation of an SPV to buy CP was a necessary step. Providing funding to issuers of CP not only drove new issuances and decreased the interest rate issuers would have to pay to borrow funds but it also decreased the level of asset sales by those that found themselves unable to raise cash and decreased the pressure on credit lines bycommercial banks.”

    http://www.levyinstitute.org/pubs/rpr_4_13.pdf

    And by bailing out AIG the Fed implicitly created moral hazard by legitimizing these CDS..

    “Finally, it guaranteed debt of Citigroup, and extended loans to insurance giant AIG, both of them insolvent firms deemed too big and too interconnected to fail. In conducting these actions, all in the name of the LLR (lender of last resort), the Fed violated the classical model in at least six ways.

    Fourth, the Fed ignored the classical admonition never to accommodate unsound borrowers when it bailed out insolvent Citigroup and AIG. Judging each firm too big and too interconnected to fail, the Fed argued that it had no choice but to aid in their rescue since each formed the hub of a vast network of counterparty credit interrelationships vital to the financial markets, such that the failure of either firm would have brought about the collapse of the entire financial system.

    Fed policymakers neglected to notice that Bagehot already had examined this argument and had shown that interconnectedness of debtor-creditor relationships and the associated danger of systemic failure constituted no good reason to bail out insolvent firms. Modern bailout critics take Bagehot one step further, contending that insolvent firms should be allowed to fail and go through receivership, recapitalization, and reorganization.

    Although assets will be “marked to market” and revalued to their natural equilibrium levels, nothing real will be lost. The firms’ capital and labor resources as well as their business relationships and specific information on borrowers will still be in place to be put to more effective and less risky uses by their new owners.””

Comments are closed.