Tightly Coupled European Banks May be Harder to Bail In than the ECB Thinks

Yves here. This post is consistent with concerns we’ve raised earlier, that the appealing-sounding “bail in” scheme is a non-starter on a practical level. US regulators have not chosen to go this route, and this is one of those occasions where their reasons are sound as opposed to bank-serving. However, that is not to minimize the not-trivial problem that American regulators face: their resolution plans aren’t workable either.

By Silvia Merler, an Affiliate Fellow at Bruegel. Originally published at Breugel.

Since the beginning of the crisis – and more so since 2010 – Europeans have been looking at the sovereign-banking “vicious circle”, tying the dismal fates of States and banks together. This has emerged as a characteristic disease during the euro crisis, and one of the stated objective of the European Banking Union project was precisely to remedy it.

The idea was basically to achieve this goal in a twofold way, ex ante and ex post. On one hand, by imposing stronger and harmonised supervisory requirements (e.g. on capital) and by empowering a third-party, independent and hopefully high-quality, supervisor to oversee their fulfillment, thus rebuilding trust in supervision and in the financial sector’s health. On the other hand, if a crisis turned out to be unavoidable, the second principle consisted in limiting recourse to taxpayers’ money as much as possible therefore preventing doubts about the damage that bank rescue would inflict to the state of public finances.

The first principle was translated into practice by the creation of a Single Supervisory Mechanism (SSM) under which, on the 4th of November, the ECB took over supervisory responsibility for banks in the euro area. The second principle concretized by the introduction of the Bank Recovery and Resolution Directive (BRRD) which gives a framework for resolution of troubled banks, and by the creation of a Single Resolution Mechanism (SRM), who should ensure consistent and homogeneous application of it. Among the other provision, the BRRD contains a set of rules for the application of bail-in in bank resolution, strengthening the involvement of private creditor that de facto is already introduced by the amended State Aid framework.

Hence, there has been a remarkable shift in the European mindset about banking crisis, from a first phase in which bail-in was a taboo, to a second one in which it is considered as a new normal and welcome practice. And there is in principle nothing bad about this idea, but the question is whether in rapidly overturning the approach, European policymakers have not overlooked important weaknesses that still exists in the system and could have important consequences in the perspective of applying these new rules.

One such point of weakness could be the fact that banks are actually very substantial creditors to other banks, via cross-holdings of share as well as bank bonds. In its latest Financial Stability and Integration Report (April 2014), the European Commission reported that between 2008 and June 2013, out of the €630 bn of banks’ capital increase in aggregate terms, €400 bn correspond to increases in interbank positions and only €230 bn represent fresh capital injected from outside the banking system. Despite declining since the pre-crisis peaks, interconnectedness across banks remains high, and as of December 2013 “the counterparty for 24 percent of Euro area banking assets (or €7,400 bn) is another Euro area bank”.

RTEmagicC_141028_italy5_01.jpg

ECB / Author calculations

Figure 1 – originally published in this Bruegel post – shows how serious the situation is in the case of Italian banks, who appear to be strongly tied together in a network of cross-holdings. Figure 2 – compiled by the Financial Times back in 2013 – shows that the Spanish system was not immune to the problem either, although less striking. In the case of Italian banks, I pointed out that strong cross holding structure (with political interference) could impede the post-stress test needed reform, but that is not the only problem it raises. As a matter of fact, we could already witness an example of possible implications at the time when the Portuguese Banco Espirito Santo was resolved, last August. The second largest shareholder of BES was in fact another bank, i.e. Credit Agricole, which on the occasion of BES restructuring ended up taking a 708 mn euro hit from its stake in BES, nearly wiping out its second-quarter net profit, which fell 97.5 percent to 17 million euros.

RTEmagicC_141120_InterOver.png

Bloomberg; FT research

Banks’ bond holdings also represent a possible risk in view of resolution. Almost 40% of securities other than shares issued by banks in the euro area are held by other banks in the euro area at the aggregate level, according to ECB data, and holdings are also affected by home bias.

The charts below show Italian and Portuguese banks’ holdings of bonds issued respectively by domestic government, other domestic banks and other domestic sectors. As a comparison, holdings of bonds issued by the corresponding sectors in other euro area countries (i.e. cross border rather than domestic holdings) are also reported. it is clear (and not new) that holdings by banks of bonds issued by the domestic government have increased a lot during the crisis, in same cases reaching back to the level of the 1990s. But what is even more noteworthy is the strong increase of holdings of bonds issued by other fellow domestic banks, which seem to have been traditionally very low but are now between 7 and 9% of total assets in these two countries.

RTEmagicC_141120_InterItalian.png

ECB / Author calculations

RTEmagicC_141120_InterPortuguese.png

ECB / Author calculations

Figure 4 shows that this is not the case for French and German banks, which not only reduced (or at least did not increase significantly) their exposure to the domestic government, but which also decreased their holdings of bonds issued by other domestic banks as percentage of total assets.

RTEmagicC_141120_InterFrench.png

ECB / Author calculations

RTEmagicC_141120_InterGerman.png

ECB / Author calculations

It should therefore be clear that this strong interconnectedness makes the European financial system vulnerable in the context of bank resolution and rises concerns for the application of bail-in, which would become very difficult due to the possible systemic implications. In fact, as in the BES case, the creditors targeted by bail in would include to a large extent other banks, which would as a consequence fall in trouble as well. It follows naturally as a conclusion that one of the first priority for the ECB in its brand new role as supervisor should be to weigh possible measures to mitigate these problems. The ECB in its prudential exercise is including a capital add-on of 1 percent to take into account the systemic relevance of banks. This is in line with CRD IV rules, which include mandatory systemic risk buffer of between 1 and 3.5 percent CET 1 of RWAs for banks that are identified by the relevant authority as globally systemically important and also gives the supervisor an option to set a buffer on ‘other’ systemically important institutions, including domestically important institutions and EU-important institutions.

On top of imposing a capital buffer to limit the effect of interconnectedness once it has built up, one possible way to go would be to act on its underlying drivers to foster more diversification ex ante. There has been a lot of talk over the last years about the need to change the framework for the risk-weighting of government bonds in banks’ assets, in order to better reflect their actual degree of risk (which certainly was way above zero, during the crisis). Reports suggest that stricter rules on banks’ exposure to single counterparties could trigger a sovereign debt portfolio rebalancing in the order of €1tn across the region. The data presented here suggest that weakening the drivers of bank-bank national interconnectedness (e.g. by means of risk weights) and fostering portfolio diversification should also rank high on the priorities, in order to foster financial stability in Europe. Otherwise, we might sooner or later discover that by trying to fix the sovereign-bank vicious cycle we have instead fuelled a bank-bank one, no less dangerous.

Print Friendly, PDF & Email

This entry was posted in Banking industry, Europe, Guest Post on by .

About Lambert Strether

Readers, I have had a correspondent characterize my views as realistic cynical. Let me briefly explain them. I believe in universal programs that provide concrete material benefits, especially to the working class. Medicare for All is the prime example, but tuition-free college and a Post Office Bank also fall under this heading. So do a Jobs Guarantee and a Debt Jubilee. Clearly, neither liberal Democrats nor conservative Republicans can deliver on such programs, because the two are different flavors of neoliberalism (“Because markets”). I don’t much care about the “ism” that delivers the benefits, although whichever one does have to put common humanity first, as opposed to markets. Could be a second FDR saving capitalism, democratic socialism leashing and collaring it, or communism razing it. I don’t much care, as long as the benefits are delivered. To me, the key issue — and this is why Medicare for All is always first with me — is the tens of thousands of excess “deaths from despair,” as described by the Case-Deaton study, and other recent studies. That enormous body count makes Medicare for All, at the very least, a moral and strategic imperative. And that level of suffering and organic damage makes the concerns of identity politics — even the worthy fight to help the refugees Bush, Obama, and Clinton’s wars created — bright shiny objects by comparison. Hence my frustration with the news flow — currently in my view the swirling intersection of two, separate Shock Doctrine campaigns, one by the Administration, and the other by out-of-power liberals and their allies in the State and in the press — a news flow that constantly forces me to focus on matters that I regard as of secondary importance to the excess deaths. What kind of political economy is it that halts or even reverses the increases in life expectancy that civilized societies have achieved? I am also very hopeful that the continuing destruction of both party establishments will open the space for voices supporting programs similar to those I have listed; let’s call such voices “the left.” Volatility creates opportunity, especially if the Democrat establishment, which puts markets first and opposes all such programs, isn’t allowed to get back into the saddle. Eyes on the prize! I love the tactical level, and secretly love even the horse race, since I’ve been blogging about it daily for fourteen years, but everything I write has this perspective at the back of it.

5 comments

  1. David Lentini

    Hence, there has been a remarkable shift in the European mindset about banking crisis, from a first phase in which bail-in was a taboo, to a second one in which it is considered as a new normal and welcome practice. And there is in principle nothing bad about this idea … .

    Maybe I’ve missed something, Yves, but how could “bail-in” be “nothing bad … in principle”? Taking depositor money to essentially subsidize our casino banks seems like a very idea on its face to me. If we’re at this point, then it’s clear that we need to liquidate and reorganize the banks.

  2. EoinW

    Square peg/round hole time. The potential for bail-ins has preoccupied my mind since the Canadian government put the idea “on the books” March 2013 because it seems to be the key moment which will decide whether we have an inflationary or deflationary future. The contradiction is quite a puzzle. Central banks, creating money endlessly, and governments, which haven’t balanced a budget my entire life, suggesting something that will lead to massive wealth destruction. Then the hyper inflation crowd muddle it further by insisting the same governments will bail-in then turn around and create more money! That makes no sense at all. Does any of this make sense? Maybe.

    From my economically illiterate position I’d like to make a suggestion for motive. Not necessarily because I’m correct, I’d simply like to hear from others on the matter(and I’ve been waiting 1 1/2 years to hear anything coherent from anyone!). I won’t point out the obvious motive that a law protecting Canada’s Big Five banks means they’ll be left standing as every credit union is wiped out. A motive consistent with our Cartel Capitalism. I won’t even be cynical and suggest they’re all idiots who destroy everything they touch, therefore bail-ins don’t have to make sense. Now if they can be used to further enrich the Country Club then perhaps they aren’t even idiots. Instead I’ll suggest the latest favourite flavour in a neo-feudal society: debt slavery.

    Who in Canada still has money? Not the younger generation. If they go through life living at home – or in a cave – and don’t go to college and never get married nor have children then they can avoid a lifetime of debt. Lead a normal life then they must play by the new rules and interest payments become a fact of life. What about my generation or Baby Boomers? Perhaps some have saved all their lives, paid off the house and don’t have to put kids through university. Most I suspect embrace debt as warmly as their credit cards. This leaves a minority from that group and Senior citizens with the only debt free finances in society. if the trend is to get everyone into debt isn’t the next natural target Pensioners? They are the ones selling the family home, down sizing and putting a nice legacy nest egg in the bank. They’ve been targeted by ZIRP for years now but the nest egg remains. You really think the banks can keep their dirty hands off it forever?

    Best of all, their main income comes from the government. They’re hardly going to take to the streets and cause trouble – bite the hand that feeds. They’ll likely continue to keep voting for the same parties they’ve been trained to vote for all their lives. What a juicy target they do make. And as pensioners keep living longer they continue to grow in numbers. You really think our government can stand for such a large and growing segment of the population continuing to be debt free?

    So don’t worry about hyper inflation. Don’t even worry about people rebelling because the ones young enough to behave so revoltingly will lose the least(maybe not at all) with a bail-in. We’ll all look at our Seniors and the bad luck that just came their way and think: “I’m glad that wasn’t me”. Isn’t that the default reaction for the 21st century western mind?

    1. DCR

      “it seems to be the key moment which will decide whether we have an inflationary or deflationary future”

      Don’t get too hung up on deflation or inflation in the conventional CPI sense. The majority of the globe’s politicians and central bankers have embarked on a plethora of insane financial/monetary experiments, some inflationary such as Japan’s printfest and currency devaluation, and some deflationary such as Germany’s nominally negative commercial bank deposit rates, but all designed to do one thing … keep the bad financial claims, which governments and global bankers have propagated with exceptional ferocity in the past twenty years, from collapsing into mass banking and government insolvency, thus eliminating their ability to skim ever greater percentages of real wealth from those who actually produce something on this planet. The keys to keeping the Ponzi alive are negative REAL interest rates (not whether they are positive or negative in nominal terms), negative REAL wage growth (not whether it is growing or shrinking nominally), and where possible, without engendering public revolution, outright asset confiscation, but the colossal fly in the ointment is that all of those over time incentivize the producers to produce less, thus shrinking the economic pie from which the bankers and politicians may skim.

Comments are closed.