Yves here. We’ve regularly derided the notion of “national competitiveness” as a an inevitable accompaniment to the oversold notion of “free trade”. Economists are aware of, yet choose to ignore, the Lipsey-Lancaster theorem, which says when an idealized state cannot be attained, moving closer to it may not be an improvement; it can often produce worse outcomes. You need to evaluate the “second best” options specifically and not go on faith.
But economists and policy makers treat “free trade” as an article of faith, and with that comes the idea that countries must compete to find customers overseas. There is too little consideration of the fallacy of expecting countries to be competitive and by implication, seek to be exporters. It is impossible for all countries to be net exporters. Moreover, countries are often better served to design their policies primarily for the benefit of domestic workers and markets, and to promote export-oriented programs only to the extent that they do not undermine conditions at home, or will clearly produce a net benefit.
By William Davies is Co-Director of the Political Economy Research Centre, Goldsmiths, University of London; introduction by Nicholas Shaxson, author of Treasure Islands. Originally publihsed at Fools’ Gold
The term “UK PLC” — the ‘PLC’ bit standing for Public Limited Company — evokes notions that whole countries behave like corporations. It is routinely trotted out by politicians in the United Kingdom: why, this FG editor even heard (and gnashed teeth at) this very term on the BBC’s Today Programme this morning, on a day when 100 UK business leaders signed an open letter suggesting that the UK must display that it is “open for business” by supplying further tax cuts and other goodies to large corporations.
Versions of these kinds of slogans, implicitly equating the interests of large corporate players with the wider national interest, can be found in most countries.
In our latest article, Will Davies asks how slogans such as these – which are intimately intertwined with notions of ‘national competitiveness’ – have managed to achieve such sway over policy-making, around the world.
Mainstream economists have never tired of arguing that nations don’t compete with each other, at least not in the way that firms or individuals do in a market. To view nations as economic competitors is to lapse into ‘mercantilism’, not just a bogey word for the economics profession, but arguably the political creed that economics was invented specifically to discredit.
Mercantilism refers to political interventions in international trade, which seek to hoard wealth in one location at the expense of another. In the 18th century, this meant seeking to amass gold, by fair means or foul. Today, it is more often those who seek to artificially weaken their currency – such as Germany or China – for the benefit of their export industries, who are accused of committing the ‘m’ word. Protectionism would be another egregious case of mercantilism.
The central argument of liberal economists, dating back to Adam Smith, is that this competitive, parochial mentality is ultimately self-defeating. The market is a ‘positive sum’ game, not a ‘zero sum game’, but only if policy-makers allow it to be so. Since Smith’s day, newspapers, political parties, think tanks, multilateral organisations, international laws and endless rounds of trade agreements have taken up this cause, to keep the mercantilist instinct at bay. Nations are not firms, and when they act in a strategic, competitive economic fashion, the net result is bad.
Why, then, has the vision and rhetoric of ‘national competitiveness’ achieved the public and political plausibility that it has? How is the entire liberal economic establishment swatted aside so easily?
I think there are three possible answers.
The first is that it is liberal economics that is deluded, and not the advocates of ‘national competitiveness’. Arguably, mercantilism never went away, even if the post-War Bretton Woods system held it in check better than bodies such as the World Trade Organisation have managed since. Political realists need only point to the existence of the lobbying industry to highlight how businesses lean on domestic politicians for favours, incentives and special treatment. Describing China, say, as ‘mercantilist’ is simply sour grapes on the part of those who had enjoyed decades of international supremacy, on the basis of an equally self-interested approach to trade.
The second possible answer is that politicians need some language through which to express economic patriotism or localism. When the Chancellor of the Exchequer turns up on yet another building site in a hard hat, he cannot stand before the cameras saying “global trade is positive sum in the aggregate, and therefore it is none of my concern whether this factory is built in Grimsby or Shenzhen”. So long as politicians are judged on national economic indicators such as growth and employment, they will seek to inject parochialism into economic policy, or at least into economic rhetoric.
But it is the third answer that brings us squarely to the distinctive aspects – and distinctive dangers – of the ‘national competitiveness’ mantra, which is unlike traditional mercantilism in key respects. For what the language of ‘national competitiveness’ does, in ways that are not simply mercantilist, is to offer a powerful analogy: the nation state is a giant corporation. Those that benefit most from this analogy are corporations themselves, although the handful of ‘super-rich’ individuals who now move between a number of global cities also benefit.
Corporations, which emerged in the late 19th century thanks to limited liability protections for shareholders and the emergence of professional management, have always been slippery and curious entities. They have their own internal rules, cultures, systems of accountability and governance mechanisms. But for the most part, these are developed for the strategic purpose of making profit for external shareholders. They are simultaneously socio-political communities and items of private property. As corporations have become more dominated by financial capital since the 1970s (albeit to the vast enrichment of senior management), the strategic approach to governance and ethics has got starker, engulfing workplaces in a sense of irony, as the language of management becomes increasingly divorced from what’s really going on.
One of the most insidious effects of representing a nation state as a corporation, as manifest in terms such as ‘UK PLC’, is to view national rules – aka ‘the law’ – in a similarly instrumentalist, malleable fashion. The rituals and symbolic practices which distinguish ‘law’ from, say, an HR code of conduct become deliberately emptied out, and law becomes viewed as one of many ‘assets’ (perhaps even as a form of ‘capital’) through which a nation can compete. Competitiveness think tanks and projects such as the World Bank’s ‘Ease of Doing Business’ rankings assess rival legal systems, in terms of how convivial they are to corporations.
Taxation, which has been historically entangled with political movements for democratic voice, becomes nothing but a ‘cost’ for the national PLC to minimize, or face the consequences. Rather than view corporate governance as a microcosmic version of parliament, parliament comes to appear like an inefficient and unpredictable model of corporate governance. Placing economic policies beyond the control of elected representatives has long been an ambition of ‘national competitiveness’ advocates, for this very reason.
There is a direct and deliberate inversion going on, as if the corporation had been in existence for centuries, while the state was a relative newcomer to global capitalism. Propping up this absurdity is a more serious issue: that, since the 1970s, states have confronted a new global horizon, in which certain forms of capital have acquired far greater powers of movement, should they be needed. Yet this dramatic increase in mobility is as much as symptom of reduced regulation as it is of technological acceleration. States made it happen.
In my book, The Limits of Neoliberalism, I define neoliberalism as the “disenchantment of politics by economics”. Carefully and deliberately, the language of politics (of law, democracy, the public, the state) has been replaced by that of economics (of efficiency, management, incentives, governance). This is facilitated through the application of measurement tools (such as competitiveness evaluations) to criticize public institutions. An inversion takes place, where states become ‘like giant corporations’, rather than corporations being ‘like mini states’. Subjecting laws and regulations to forms of cost-benefit analysis, as if their purpose were indistinguishable from efficiency, is a symptom of this. This then opens the door to private consultants to advise on how such efficiency might be increased, while concealing the question – ‘efficiency for whom?’
The liberal critique of ‘mercantilism’ is valuable up to a point. But economists are naive if they believe they are simply in a scientific debate about the best route to welfare maximisation. There are different accounts of what welfare and efficiency mean, different paths to get them adopted by politicians, and very rarely is anyone acting on behalf of some vaporous economic aggregate.
The language of ‘national competitiveness’ has served as a devastatingly successful political land-grab on the part of financial and corporate interests, and needs to be seen as such, if it is to be discredited.
‘Tis amazing when you look up the phrase “Beggar thy neighbor” in the neo-lib phrasebook that it is narrowly defined as something to do with import tariffs. But not currency wars or stealing multinational corporations with the “race to the bottom” in corporate tax rates. Or certainly not stealing jobs or entire industries. But something terrible happens if you use tariffs to fine tune how you want your domestic economy to work. Like maybe countries only trade in stuff they need.
I keep losing these things. Some post somewhere some time ago described corporations as “private governments”, in a strong parallel with what Davies says at more length here. Eliminating any difference between public and private can make Uck Pluck seem like a natural thing.
Well most corporations are centrally planned economies internally.
I think the above quote sums up my fundamental disconnect when discussing corporations. I have always viewed a corporation as a min-state that has gradually become larger and more powerful than most nation-states. I’m not ready to concede that any one corporation is more powerful than major Western States but as an aggregate I believe that they are more powerful than even the US since they ultimately control US policy.
I could not stick it out in politics (I worked on Democratic elections). I continuously ran into this problem when discussing societal problems. People would always ask how to make something more efficient as if that is the reason why people are hungry, homeless, or abused. The government needed to be more efficient in doling out ever smaller amounts while becoming more competitive with other municipalities then states (eventually countries) in order to attract jobs that will be a tax drain since the corporation is not taxed on property or income for 10+ years.
Great post.
We need to be focusing on democratizing our corporations (and states), not corpratizing our states.
The sad thing is, I think that most academic economists don’t even understand the role they are playing in the looting of society. The poor fools actually believe the hocus pocus they’re spouting…
Excellent post! I think the word “competitive” is one of the most impressive examples of neoliberal doublespeak that I have ever encountered. In almost every instance, when the word is used, it could be replaced with “designed to further fatten the already obscenely rich while making the lives of most poor souls even worse.”
Consider job postings that proclaim proudly that the employer “pays competitive wages and offers flexible hours.” Upon closer examination what this means is precisely opposite of what they hope the applicants take it to mean. The employer will pay the absolute minimum they can, in a given market, for people with the skills they need– and seek to limit their hours to stay below a threshold that might force them (due to the remnants of legal labor protections left over from he New Deal era) to assume any meaningful responsibility for their workers.
Almost makes you feel like most of us folks are gladiators, don’t it???
Rather than “compete” with transnational kleptocrats in their own game, we need to start struggling mightily against them– until their deadly, destructive game is finally over!
http://www.iww.org/projects/isc
Wobblies in the house!
Surprised no one else has mentioned it, but the social media buttons appear about half way into the article and the last half of the article is in a narrow column on the right-hand side. Formatting weirdness…
Noticed this as well.
Sorry, I was provided the HTML and the problem didn’t show in the “visual” view (in the backstage) but I would have caught it with “preview”. Go figure. Fixed now.
1. All four US presidents carved on Mt. Rushmore were unabashed protectionists. They took this nation from a backwards agricultural colony to the greatest industrial power that the (then) world had ever seen, and with the highest standard of living. Protectionism works! Three cheers for mercantilism!
2. Why can’t ‘competitiveness’ be applied to the elites? I mean, if a CEO makes $100 million a year and drives their company into the ground, surely we would be more ‘competitive’ if we found a CEO somewhere who could drive their company into the ground for substantially less in wages and benefits?
Remember also: the point of banking and finance is to allocate resources efficiently – which means at the lowest possible costs! FIRE profits of more than a few percent are grossly inefficient. We need FIRE cost reform! If markets need affordable labor costs, why not affordable financing costs? Surely the IMF should make it contingent that a nation receiving bailouts tear up the contracts and retirement programs of the bankers, financial profits should be taxed at confiscatory rates, etc. How can any nation progress without financial market reform and flexibility?
3. There is, of course, no such thing as efficiency in the absolute. A car that get 10 miles per gallon of gas is grossly inefficient at translating gasoline into movement – but very efficient at consuming gasoline! Similarly a person getting 20 dollars an hour is very inefficient at turning money into labor – but very efficient at turning labor into money. Prosperity is therefore about maximizing labor market ‘inefficiency’ as seen from the point of view of a rentier, but maximizing it as seen from the point of view of a worker…
This is as simple as I can put it:
Feudalism is additive, over the time it can see, always with an expectable C, taxing physical, intellectual and spiritual mobility. Transportation, public education, and church, the corporation, is unreliable, except to inflate RE at the expense of economic mobility. Take care of your feet, expect G to eliminate your path of travel, and keep your own counsel when it comes to point C. Build out the AC multiplexer of DC circles as you go.
One little sidelight. A UK company called Ascenta developed a high-altitude solar-powered drone. Sounds good for “UK plc.”? Well, maybe it was until Facebook (a non-UK corp.) bought the company in 2014. Even if Ascenta continues to manufacture in the UK, the profits will be diverted into some low-tax jurisdiction and won’t benefit the UK much. And if it’s offshored, well, from the UK’s point of view the inventors may as well have stayed in bed.