By Tanya Rawal-Jindia, a researcher at Tricontinental: Institute for Social Research. Originally published at openDemocracy as part of ourEconomy’s ‘Decolonising the economy’ series.
Amazon.com Inc. was brought to court by the U.S. Internal Revenue Service (IRS) in 2017 for transfer pricing discrepancies. In 2005 and 2006, the multinational tech company had transferred $255 million in royalty payments to its tax haven in Luxembourg, but according to the IRS these royalty payments should have amounted to $3.5 billion. This transfer pricing adjustment would have increased Amazon’s federal tax payments by more than $1 billion.
Even for the U.S., a country with decent (although waning) infrastructure, the loss of this much cash in federal tax revenue is substantial. Take for instance the water crisis in Flint, Michigan – if the city’s estimated costs of $55 million to replace the pipes are accurate, then Amazon’s tax payments could have saved the 100,000 residents from lead poisoning 18 times over.
Water supply is not the only infrastructural problem that arises when export countries suffer from a dramatic loss of tax revenue. Education, hospitals, telecommunications, and roads also decline. And in developing countries – the countries that suffer the most severe effects of transfer and trade mispricing – this infrastructure is often never properly constructed in the first place. The much needed cash is, instead, sitting in a tax haven.
The anonymous whistleblower who, in 2015, leaked the 11.5 million documents that we now know as the ‘Panama Papers’ shared in a manifesto that ‘income inequality’ was their motivation in revealing the levels of financial abuse that tax havens create. A key concern for the whistleblower was that tax havens are ‘metastasizing’ across the earth’s surface – 214,000 offshore entities are cited in the ‘Panama Papers’.
The ‘metastasizing’ certainly continued after the release of the Panama Papers – just two years later, a U.S. PIRG study found that 73% of Fortune 500 companies operated 9,755 tax haven subsidiaries. And this problem of tax havens did not form overnight. The whistleblower echoes Raymond C. Offenheiser, the former president of Oxfam America, in his 2006 description of tax havens as being ‘the core of a global system that allows large corporations and wealthy individuals to avoid paying their fair share, depriving governments, rich and poor, of the resources they need to provide vital public services and tackle rising inequality.’
Tax havens are a geo-political nightmare and transfer pricing and mispricing are accounting tricks to get money into tax havens. The former is legal while the latter is illegal – but the boundary between them is virtually non-existent.
Transfer Mispricing, Defined
There’s a wide range of tax avoidance games played by multinationals: transfer mispricing, abusive transfer pricing, trade misinvoicing, Base Erosion and Profit Shifting (BEPS), and re-invoicing. All of these fall under the umbrella of trade mispricing, or the intentional falsification of transactions on an international level. Arguably, the polynymity of this deceptive practice is evidence of its ubiquity. But ‘thievery’ could just as well replace any of these titles.
The short-term goals of misinvoicing vary. In some cases the desired outcome is to dodge capital controls (a strategy commonly used in emerging markets to reduce rapid cash outflows). In other cases, the incentive for misinvoicing is to claim tax incentives or avoid paying duty. Generally, the scheme is this: shift profits out of high tax countries and into low tax countries, or tax havens, while ensuring that the majority of expenses are assigned to high tax countries.
In 2015, Global Financial Integrity (GFI) published a study revealing that in 2013 an astounding US$1.1 trillion was stolen annually—or nearly $3 billion a day—from developing countries due to trade mispricing. If you wonder why developing countries seem rather slow to develop, here’s a big part of the answer.
Depleting the Tax Base, Perpetuating Poverty
Transfer pricing – the pricing of commodities traded between or within multinational enterprises (MNEs) – is a legal practice and a key feature of cross-border and intra-firm transactions. The United Nations prefers to use the broader phrase ‘trade pricing’ in addressing this practice and defines it as a “normal incident of the operations of multinational enterprises (MNEs).” Because the word ‘incident’ evokes concern, it should not go unnoticed.
One of the most disruptive consequences of transfer pricing is that international transactions are now governed by the monopolistic interests of an MNE group. That is, market forces no longer control transactions because, with transfer pricing, an increasing percentage of global trade (this includes the international transfer of goods and services, capital, and intangible goods, or intellectual property) now occurs as an internal practice between affiliated entities.
Theoretically, internal transfer pricing is supposed to follow the arm’s length principle, which is that transfer prices should be controlled and recorded as if internal trades were happening amongst independent entities, or at “arm’s length.” But as the IRS case against Amazon.com reveals, proving arm’s length is not so straightforward. So while the “arm’s length principle” is very much written into place (Brazil is listed as the only country without domestic legislation or regulation that makes reference to the arm’s length principle), even research from the Organisation for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD) and the United Nations recognises that this principle is very much impossible to implement.
Unable to ignore the ease with which a company could engage in abusive transfer pricing, the OECD and the G20 countries first drafted the ‘BEPS Action Plan’ in 2013 as part of a broader effort to enhance transparency for tax administrations to assess transfer pricing. Base Erosion and Profit Shifting undermines the integrity of any tax system. But the direct harm BEPS creates for individual taxpayers and governments was only part of the motivation for implementing the 2013 action plan. The other motivating factor was the added risk to businesses, including the risk to an MNE’s reputation in the event that their effective tax rate was viewed as being “too low” thereby impeding “fair competition” locally. With this latter motivation, little promise ought to be expected from the plan as it maintains a focus on risks brought to MNEs themselves rather than to wider society.
Setting potential reputational risks aside, the incentive for companies to strategically misprice trade or shift their profits is to avoid tax or duty payments and shield wealth. And while there is no single way to avoid tax payments and dues, there is one necessary component: tax haven subsidiaries.
The Art of Creating Political Asylum Networks for Wealth
Tax haven subsidiaries function as cash canals to transport taxable profits with the goal of lowering or, if you are Amazon Inc., entirely avoiding tax payments. But this requires a financial sleight of hand. Take for instance the “Goldcrest” method Amazon used in Luxembourg. It shifted its intellectual property rights (or intangibles) that were held by its US parent company to its subsidiary, Amazon Lux. The subsidiary then collected royalties tax-free on international sales. Google and Ikea similarly decided to play the “Going Dutch” move, using their subsidiaries in the Netherlands.
The “Swiss Sidestep” is another tax play, and rather than royalty payments, “management service fees” are the key element. By paying a value-added service fee to a sister company in a European tax haven, a company can “side-step” tax payments by converting profits into fees. And, then, of course there is the privacy and protection that a company gets on the island of Mauritius – with the “Mauritius Manoeuvre” a person can send their cash to Mauritius to avoid income tax and then bring it back – without a trace – as “foreign investment”.
Each of these fictional narratives that frame the legal movement of cash across borders has one theme in common: wealth-protection and, therefore, poverty-production.
The Colonial Undertones of Transfer Pricing
It is not the case that some industries are more prone than others to transfer mispricing, or even that developed countries are immune to this manipulative business practice – the IRS case against Amazon is a great example of this. But, it is the case that developing countries are more vulnerable to the impact of transfer mispricing. Suppose a company extracts 2 megatons (MT) of cobalt from Papua New Guinea (PNG) and then exports the 2 MT (or 1 million kilograms) at the price of 5 USD per kilogram, but imports into Canada – by way of Mauritius or the Netherlands – the same 2 MT of cobalt at the price of 10 USD. The result for PNG is the loss of tax revenue on 5 million dollars. Even at a mere 5% tax rate with these modest and imaginative figures, a loss of $250,000 USD for PNG is significant.
The impact of trade and transfer mispricing on developing countries is not just monetary. There are a series of moral effects as well. In the hypothetical PNG scenario, for instance, one glaring concern that arises from this manipulative business practice is the implication that the people of PNG are somehow unaware of the value of their own resources. A red flag must be raised to the psychological impact of pricing discrepancies that suggest cobalt, somehow, has a lesser value within the borders of PNG than within, say, Canada or Belgium.
Trade and transfer (mis)pricing are symptoms of an ongoing colonial hangover. Given that transfer (mis)pricing is at the centre of operations of MNEs, then the only way to remove this jewel in the crown of every MNE is to dismantle the multinational enterprise as it exists today. A first necessary step would be to introduce strict and enforceable regulations that help guide us away from such damaging relations of production.
1. Break the tax system (legally or illegally) of the developing country to be looted
2. Sign bilateral trade deals on behalf of any given corporation that sees a looting oportunity.
3. Corrupt the elites to the point of keeping them enough satisfied and lazy to allow for 1. and 2.
4. Allow some welfare to keep morale from sinking to the bottom.
5. Use finance tools to keep them on their knees when applying any other measure
6.Close your border to desperate migrants. After all, the looting has nothing to do with their desperation, is just their corrupt elite’s fault
7.Lecture developing countries on their obvious failures
Three more are needed for a decalogue
8. Wash.
9. Rinse.
10. Repeat.
8. perpetuate the idea that you are too big to compete
9. fool yourself into thinking you are accumulating wealth
10. maintain labor, trade and externalized cost arbitrage as if they were rational behavior
The dark side of FDI by MNC that doesn’t receive as much attention as it should. Poverty production is baked into the system as it aligns the interests of local politicians and MNC seeking high yields from their investments:
1. A politician goes on an investment road show.
2. Declares their country “open for business”.
3. Outfoxes rival countries through unsustainable incentives for the MNC to invest into a factory creating (crap below living wage) jobs.
4. Politician is lauded for “bringing in investment and creating jobs” and derives significant political mileage from this act of effectively selling their country to foreign investors who now have unimpeded latitude to bleed the nation dry using shenanigans like transfer (mis)pricing.
5. The politician gets his election and everything else accrues to rapacious capital.
Meanwhile, ISDS is always on hand to yank away any recourse the country being sucked dry might have down the line.
Nothing short of robust, internationally coordinated deterrent mechanisms backed by enforcement with real teeth will curb this. Fragmented country level efforts to combat this neocolonial pillaging won’t be enough as countries with the temerity to fight back will be punished with soaring risk scoring on country risk indices while their “investment grade” status is yanked away. Additionally moral culpability must also fall on the army of consultants who make all this possible.
Amen!
Numbers 1-5 apply domestically, as well. Your scenario sounds exactly like what happened in Wisconsin with Gov. Scott Walker and the Foxconn ripoff. Walker was finally booted out of office once the voters realized they’d been had.
Charge the executives with a conspiracy to defraud the Government.
Take them in front of a jury of their peers
………
Wouldn’t their peers just say “they didn’t do anything we aren’t doing, therefore “not guilty””?
Probably not. Juries don’t take kindly to aristocratic privilege. The real problem is that the corporations can always avoid a jury trial. If we could REQUIRE these trials to be juried, we might start getting somewhere.
So look at the opportunity for Libra to make a killing, and it would seem perfectly legal. Adam Levitin, yesterday, gave a rundown of all the possible disincentives for FB’s Libra scheme. It doesn’t work as a payment system at all, for the high-minded purposes given (banking all the great unwashed). But look at this misbehavior of MNEs and then think Libra. There’s no way to regulate it because it is not a sovereign currency. Zuck and his partners could be planning to set up their own “subsidiary” tax haven into which they could dump profits for customers and themselves, convert them into fees, take their share and hold the rest for safe keeping. Or any of a million little schemes to make huge profits. Look at the blatant Cobalt example – paying PNG half of the value of the commodity, selling for twice that amount, screwing PNG and any taxing authority along the way. “Transfer pricing” is a wide open opportunity.
Zuck and his partners could be planning to set up their own “subsidiary” tax haven into which they could dump profits for customers and themselves, convert them into fees, take their share and hold the rest for safe keeping.
They have already. Libra is based in Switzerland.
Again. Why not just abolish the corporate income tax altogether abd rather place the point of incidence of corporate profits on both the wealth and income of the owners, the stock and bondholders? Much of the incentive to such behaviors would then become pointless and “off-shore”, (which is really mostly on-shore) would dissipate. The armies of lawyers and accountants required to operate such scheme his a huge waste of effort. They could better be deployed elsewhere, such as in enforcing SEC regulations. (That was a joke). And the incomes and wealth of the corporate elites are largely fictitious capital anyway, speculatively making money off of money without actually producing anything and should be clawed back and redirected to pro-social purposes. So tax them as high as you please. A corporation worth $100 bn has far more resources the indulge in such scheme than an individual worth $1 bn and individuals are far easier to criminally prosecute than corps. (“the Holder doctrine”). Don’t just kvetch; propose functional solutions.
Now you are talking
I think the attempt to assess tax due on the basis of corporate profits has been proved to not work. The lawyers and accountants study the laws and invent ways to circumnavigate the legislature’s intent and they get the money that should have come to the country. Our ability to define our intent in precise words always fails. There may be a consensual tax man involved in approving the avoidance too. We need another way of ensuring that government does not fall totally under the heel of big business as it appears to have done in the west.
What about turnover? Or, these days of market manipulation, what about share price? There must be a great many corporate statistis from which a revenue collector can choose without prior notification to the constant avoider. This apparent government helplessness is suspicious to me.
I remember reading an analysis of the financials for a certain British confectionery company with a long history, now owned by Kraft foods, that shall remain nameless. The author painstakingly followed the trail through a web of holding companies and related parties, and concluded that the net effect was that the local company was providing a large interest free loan to its parent, then borrowing it all back again at 8% interest.
Given the choice, Capitalists will do what is most profitable.
It has simply become more profitable for Capitalists to destroy, rather than to build.To plunder, rather than produce.
So instead of the powerful spending their time figuring how best to serve society, they spend their time figuring out how to steal from it, and the people, and to legalize such theft.
Since all the powerful are doing it, they will succeed beyond their wildest dreams.
They are creating the horror they fear. And they will blame you, and the governments they have corrupted and enslaved. Blaming the victim is an old and well worn tactic of the rich and powerful.
There is nothing you can do to stop it. You are not the rich. You are not the powerful.
Capitalism consumes its present, and when that is gone, its future. And now it consumes yours.
Capitalism cannot restrain itself. And there is no longer anything left which can.
Except, of course, the hard edges of reality. And the earth.