Yves here. After taking a look last week at Wikipedia as a monopolist, Micheal Olenick is continuing his tour of practices that are economically harmful. With noncompetes, as in non-competitive employment agreements, businessmen haven’t even deigned to come up with a faux-friendly label to hide their intent of stymieing competition. From the Economic Policy Institute at the end of 2019:
Noncompete agreements are employment provisions that ban workers at one company from going to work for, or starting, a competing business within a certain period of time after leaving a job. It is not difficult to see that noncompetes may be contributing to weak wage growth, given that changing jobs is how workers often get a raise. And given that noncompetes limit the ability of individuals to start businesses or take other jobs, it also is not difficult to see that noncompetes may be contributing to the declines in dynamism in the U.S. labor market. But how common are they? This report uses data from a national survey of private-sector American business establishments to investigate the extent of noncompete usage. We find:
- Roughly half, 49.4%, of responding establishments indicated that at least some employees in their establishment were required to enter into a noncompete agreement. Nearly a third, 31.8%, of responding establishments indicated that allemployees in their establishment were required to enter into a noncompete agreement, regardless of pay or job duties.
- The survey data do not allow us to determine the precise share of workers nationwide that are subject to noncompete agreements. However, we can calculate a range, and we find that somewhere between 27.8% and 46.5% of private-sector workers are subject to noncompetes.
And even though, as this post explains long form, the success of most of Silicon Valley’s biggest names depended on the founders being able to leave their former employers and hire key early employees, these tech titans tried to close the gate. As Mark Ames wrote in Pando in 2014:
In early 2005, as demand for Silicon Valley engineers began booming, Apple’s Steve Jobs sealed a secret and illegal pact with Google’s Eric Schmidt to artificially push their workers wages lower by agreeing not to recruit each other’s employees, sharing wage scale information, and punishing violators. On February 27, 2005, Bill Campbell, a member of Apple’s board of directors and senior advisor to Google, emailed Jobs to confirm that Eric Schmidt “got directly involved and firmly stopped all efforts to recruit anyone from Apple.”…
These secret conversations and agreements between some of the biggest names in Silicon Valley were first exposed in a Department of Justice antitrust investigation launched by the Obama Administration in 2010. That DOJ suit became the basis of a class action lawsuit filed on behalf of over 100,000 tech employees whose wages were artificially lowered — an estimated $9 billion effectively stolen by the high-flying companies from their workers to pad company earnings — in the second half of the 2000s. Last week, the 9th Circuit Court of Appeals denied attempts by Apple, Google, Intel, and Adobe to have the lawsuit tossed, and gave final approval for the class action suit to go forward. A jury trial date has been set for May 27 in San Jose, before US District Court judge Lucy Koh, who presided over the Samsung-Apple patent suit.
In a related but separate investigation and ongoing suit, eBay and its former CEO Meg Whitman, now CEO of HP, are being sued by both the federal government and the state of California for arranging a similar, secret wage-theft agreement with Intuit (and possibly Google as well) during the same period.
The secret wage-theft agreements between Apple, Google, Intel, Adobe, Intuit, and Pixar (now owned by Disney) are described in court papers obtained by PandoDaily as “an overarching conspiracy” in violation of the Sherman Antitrust Act and the Clayton Antitrust Act, and at times it reads like something lifted straight out of the robber baron era that produced those laws. Today’s inequality crisis is America’s worst on record since statistics were first recorded a hundred years ago — the only comparison would be to the era of the railroad tycoons in the late 19th century.
The parties settled the case in 2015. It’s a shame it didn’t go to trial, because the documentary evidence in the filing looked awfully hard to ‘splain away, and any damages could have been trebled.
By Michael Olenick, a research fellow at INSEAD whose recent articles can be found at innowiki.org and Blue Ocean Thinking
Following up on last week’s piece about Wikipedia as an overlooked monopoly, I’ve written this piece about a different type of unrecognized monopoly, noncompetes. These agreements monopolize employee mobility after the employee has left an employer. Most analysis focuses on whether the agreements are legal (depends), moral (rarely), or necessary (virtually never). However, there is far too little thought about the macroeconomic effects of noncompetes on business. This follows a fallacious assumption that what senior executives want tends to be good for business, and they frequently want an ability to control former employees for life. However, much like a child who would eat candy for dinner if allowed, certain behaviors are prohibited because they’re bad for health. Noncompetes fall squarely into this category. California rarely allows the enforcement of noncompetes.
———
Many of the largest businesses in the world would have been stifled as startups if non-compete agreements were legal in California. Part of the magic of both Silicon Valley and Hollywood is California’s near refusal to enforce these arguably anti-capitalistic economically harmful contract clauses.
Some background…
An Insufferable Bigot
The outbursts, public humiliations, and surprise lie detector tests should’ve been enough. After all, teenage Eugene Kleiner and his family hadn’t fled Hitler at fifteen to take orders from a blowhard bigot. Yet that was the exact situation he was facing.
A young Eugene wrote to his dad asking for advice and help.
Arthur Rock was a misfit. He joined the army hoping to fight Nazis only to be deployed shortly after Hitler surrendered. Rock graduated from Syracuse University, which he attended on the G.I. Bill then, immediately after, went to Harvard Business School, also on the G.I. bill. The Jewish son of an east coast candy store owner sat elbow-to-elbow with the very gentile sons of Captains of Industry.
After business school, Rock worked briefly as a securities analyst then joined the corporate finance department at Hayden, Stone & Company. He certainly wasn’t a blueblood Hayden or Stone but they quickly found a quirky job for him, finding funding for young companies. Rock quickly focused on the burgeoning high-tech sector where the fast-pace of change was fun but also challenging. Besides, nobody else wanted to help startups which, at the time, were typically funded by wealthy patrons much like an art production.
Kleiner Sr. circulated his son’s letter where it eventually found Rock and the two connected.
Along with a handful of other scientists, Kleiner had landed what he thought would be a dream job working with Nobel Prize winner William Shockley, co-inventor of the transistor. Shockley’s transistors were tiny “solid-state” materials that did the same job as vacuum tubes though they were far smaller, more rugged, faster, and required vastly less power. Transistors could revolutionize the world, dramatically shrinking electronic technology in terms of price, size, and power usage while increasing processing power. Because transistors were far more rugged they were also suitable for military applications.
After accepting the job, Kleiner found some serious problems. First, Shockley had been more of a business manager than an engineer on the transistor project. The actual scientists who invented the technology, John Bardeen and Walter Brattain, were not at all involved in Shockley’s business and weren’t especially thrilled with Shockley after the latter tried to steal credit for the entire invention.
Besides being a phony, Shockley was a verbally abusive overt racist micro-manager.
The Jewish refugee was uncomfortable working with a man who advocated a “Voluntary Sterilization Bonus Plan” and is quoted saying things like “Nature has color-coded groups of individuals so that statistically reliable predictions of their adaptability to intellectually rewarding and effective lives can easily be made and profitably be used by the pragmatic man-in-the-street.”
Then there were the working conditions at Shockley Semiconductor. Scientists were prohibited from talking to one another, Shockley randomly administered lie detector test, and, as if all the rest wasn’t enough, many of Kleiner’s co-workers didn’t believe Shockley would ever release a useful product.
A New Industry
Rock was intrigued. He’d heard about transistors and semiconductors and they sounded both exciting and commercially valuable. He hatched a plan with Kleiner to find him and his colleagues a new home. About three dozen companies returned blank stares, shaken heads, or hints of intrigue coupled with refusals to form a new group that might politically upset current employees focused on vacuum tubes.
Finally, Rock found Sherman Fairchild.
Sherman’s dad, George Winthrop, dropped out of school at 14 to apprentice as a printer. He soon purchased a newspaper and then branched into other business ventures. One promising business included employee timeclocks manufactured by the Bundy Manufacturing Company.
Bundy was good at innovation and manufacturing but struggled with sales so Winthrop formed a sales organization, the International Time Record Company. In 1911, International Time merged into a new entity, the Computing-Tabulating-Recording Company (CTR). Eventually, in 1924, CTR was renamed International Business Machines … IBM. Winthrop was the Chairman and Sherman his sole heir.
Despite being fabulously wealthy, Winthrop was into technology and inventing. An aerial photography system did well. Rock convinced Sherman to fund a new division, Fairchild Semiconductor, then hire Eugene and the other engineers.
Altogether, eight engineers left Shockley for Fairchild in 1957. Shockley was livid, branding them the Traitorous Eight.
About the only thing Shockley had done well, albeit inadvertently, was move from the east coast, where technology businesses were based, to the sleepy college town of Palo Alto, California. Accustomed to life out west, the Traitorous Eight established Fairchild Semiconductorin the same area.
Life was vastly better at Fairchild. One of their major technology disagreements with Shockley was what material to use for their semiconductors. Shockley favored geranium; the others favored silicon. They created a silicon semiconductor then sold lots of chips, earning piles of money for both Fairchild and themselves. Other companies were formed nearby to focus on silicon chips and the area picked up a nickname, Silicon Valley.
Over time, the brainiacs became frustrated. Their stock options had vested leaving all the men relatively wealthy though money wasn’t their sole quest in life. Over time, they left to form or join other companies: National Semiconductor, Texas Instruments, and others. Eugene Kleiner left to help startup businesses and eventually co-founded the venerable venture capital firm, Kleiner Perkins.
Finally, tired of “east coast bureaucracy,” what was left of members of the Traitorous Eight again called Rock to help fund and form another new company, one they’d own that’d be managed on the west coast. He funded and helped form the business, naming it Intel.
Two Stinky Hippies
Rock kept funding companies and, eventually, moved west to help manage the new businesses. He became spectacularly wealthy but, despite the financial success, was always looking for new businesses to fund (at 94 years old he’s still regularly in the office).
One person he kept in touch with was a young marketing manager at Fairchild and Intel, Mike Markkula. Thanks to stock options, Markkula had retired at the age of 32 and spent his days hanging out and checking out the new companies that sprung up around Silicon Valley. He’d invested seed capital into one of them and invited Rock to visit it at a trade show.
Rock described to me that trade shows were common in Silicon Valley back in the day. Businesses would show off their technology to one another, to customers, and to investors. Rock and Markkula walked through the stands, plenty of which were empty because the businesses folded before the show opened. None of the booths had more than a few people until they approached the one Markkula brought Rock to see.
There was a throng of people excited about a new desktop microcomputer, one priced for and usable by ordinary people. Markkula pushed his way to the front with Rock and found, in Rock’s words, two stinky hippies both named Steve. The hippie movement from up the street in San Francisco had spread south and fused with the startup culture of Silicon Valley. One of the Steve’s was barefoot. They were absolutely not presentable; entirely unsuitable as businessmen.
Rock wasn’t happy with their demeanor but couldn’t ignore the mesmerized crowd. The barefoot one, Steve Jobs, did almost all the talking while the other, Steve Wozniak, seemed to have more of an engineering role.
To this day, Rock remembers he didn’t much care for either of these men. But the consumer interest around them was unmistakable and he thought their little computer might sell well. He invested and took a seat on their Board of Directors of their company, Apple, where his presence was a steadying and reassuring force for other investors.
Noncompetes
Except in rare instances, California does not allow the enforceability of non-compete agreements, contracts that prohibit an employee from competing with a business for some amount of time after the employee leaves.
If the state did allow non-competes, it’s virtually certain Shockley would’ve insisted on them stifling the Traitorous Eight and drowning Silicon Valley when it was still a baby. Furthermore, Jobs and Wozniak both worked for Atari at one point and Wozniak worked for HP when Apple was founded; non-competes would’ve stopped those businesses. Similarly, Rock, the man who coined the term “venture capital,” was able to go out on his own due to an absence of noncompetes. Kleiner’s firm went on to fund Amazon, Google, Compaq, Electronic Arts, Sun Microsystems, America Online, and Twitter among countless others.
Noncompetes allow slow, weak, and lazy businesses to continue in their ways rather than face competition from smarter, harder working, more nimble upstarts. They’re a relic of serfdom from the days when workers were locked in guilds through aristocratic rules about who could do what. These rules were designed specifically to stifle capitalism and competition.
Oftentimes, noncompetes are designed simply to harass and businesses frequently interpret the agreements well beyond their scope. For example, I was once falsely accused of breaking a non-compete when my wife took a job at a company that competed with one I’d been at. As if that wasn’t bad enough, the company with the non-compete had refused to hire my wife and called her “useless” (which is why I quit in the first place). I lived in California so rather than sue, the non-compete business started a slander campaign thwarting me in other areas (and, yes, in hindsight I should’ve sued for defamation).
There is simply no legitimate reason for noncompetes. Proponents argue noncompetes protect trade secrets but that argument is bogus. Trade secrets remain protected to the point that violating a trade secret is often not only a civil issue but also a crime; nobody is advocating that employees should be able to steal proprietary information.
Real studies in the use of oppressive noncompetes show how ridiculous these arguments are. For example, Jimmy John’s sandwich shop used to insist on non-competes for its sandwich makers despite they had no secrets at all. Even if sandwich-making were somehow secret — a ludicrous proposition on its own — Jimmy John’s sandwiches are made in plain view of customers. Jimmy John’s dropped the practice after losing several lawsuits and a flood of negative publicity. The noncompetes were useless and harmful to the business, not helpful in any way.
People often wonder what the “secret sauce” behind Silicon Valley is. The weather is nice but there are plenty of places with nice weather. Stanford and Berkeley are great schools but, again, there are lots of Universities around the world. Lots of investment funds are available but money also flows in New York, Chicago, London, Tel Aviv, and Singapore. A creative bohemian attitude? Nothing tops Paris.
One notable thing that sets Silicon Valley apart from other tech hubs is California’s refusal to enforce non-compete contracts. This is good for the economy, good for businesses that are forced to compete to keep their employees, and good for capitalism itself.
Anecdotal evidence on how wide-spread non-competes have become. A couple of years ago, I was talking to one of my neighbors who was a personal trainer at a local gym. He told me that he left his job to go on his own – rented a small office to work with people there. Then, his former employer (who lived half the year in Paris and for whom the gym was more of a vanity project than anything) slapped him with a cease-and-desist order based on his non-compete. It got thrown out in court eventually – the non-compete was unenforceable -, but only after 6 months and it effectively killed my neighbor’s startup operation.
This is a non-compete against an hourly employee – nothing to do with IP. And, no, he could not seek redress through the courts against his former employer because it was too expensive for him.
I’m basically trapped at the company I work for, as just about any place where my skills would directly transfer would be considered a competitor by my employer. They forced a smaller company to revoke a job offer made to one of my coworkers even though the smaller company is more of an indirect competitor.
The only real options to leave are to go to a customer or business partner.
Typo – germanium, not geranium
Oh, brother. Does this remind me of a story from the Arizona Slim File or what?
Our tale starts on Facebook. (Yes, I know. The Faceborg.)
It was the year 2014, and I was freelancing as a copywriter. One of my friends from the Book needed help with creating continuing education materials for teachers. Would I be interested?
You bet I was.
For eight months, I had an absolute blast writing continuing ed modules for that company. I could freelance from Tucson, the money was good, and the company paid promptly.
Then came that infamous First Monday of April 2015. I was informed that the company was giving the freelancers a vacation. Without pay, of course.
Well. My primary client’s work had dried up. I had to scramble to find other work.
Note to self: Don’t have a primary client. Because when the work dries up, you’re dead in the water. Have a variety of clients who keep you busy.
In late 2015, this company came back to me, but, alas, they had cut their payment rate. I did the work they asked for, but let’s just say that the thrill was gone.
Then came early 2016. Said company was sold. My Faceborg friend informed me that the purchasing company had all sorts of work! And that I’d be really busy!
Me? I was less than impressed. I told my friend that, if I was going to be so busy, then it was time to start talking about employment.
Uh-uh, said my friend. The new company will NOT hire you or any of the other writers as employees. However, new company was requiring the freelancers to sign a non-compete agreement.
What the [family blog] was up with that? I took the agreement to my attorney and he strongly advised against signing it. So I didn’t.
That was the end of the line with me and that company, but, hey. I wasn’t going to sign something that would handcuff me as a freelancer.
Moral of the story: These agreements are insidious and they have spread to the world of freelancing.
I help run a SW contracting company. We are setup as an Oregon C Corp.
Often, when negotiating a master service agreement with a client, there will be a non-compete section. We always strike that section. Usually there isn’t any pushback, but sometimes there is.
Our answer is that:
– We are under NDA with our clients and we won’t disclose our client list to you.
– We *may* or *may not* be currently working for one or more of your competitors.
– We will guard your IP and ensure we honor all confidentiality agreements.
– If you don’t our terms, find someone else.
We do device drivers, process recovery, board support packages and Linux stuff in the embedded SW space.
So far they have always folded.
We strike the drug test section too.
Even though we are very small, being setup as a C Corp is a major benefit for us. For one thing all negotiations are now Corp to Corp. As a C Corp we are providing SW services to a client. Our employees are all W-2 employees, so we have been able to dodge the various “contractor” term limits as well.
Having a diverse list of *good* clients has saved us many times. During the telecom meltdown, the 2008/2009 financial meltdown and again during the times of Covid.
It also helps that we have the ability to say no. If you can’t get up and walk away from the table in a negotiation… you aren’t negotiating. You are just talking about the terms of surrender you are going to accept.
The three traps for unwary independent contractors: warranty & indemnification, non-disclosure, and non-compete. As a contract advisor to freelance and independent contractor writers, I constantly found overbearing clauses in the writers’ contracts in all three categories, even in states that didn’t allow them or severely restricted them. They teach a broader lesson, that our legal system, like our elections, is a mish-mash of lawful and unlawful practices that rely on caveat emptor to an extreme.
Incidentally, in most European countries the clauses are allowed but employees that sign them are granted very large bonuses, either throughout their employment or after. In Germany, for instance, the post-employment term can be 24 months and the bonus throughout that period is 50% of salary.
Employees of Oracle & Tesla and other Silicon Valley companies moving to Austin are going to be shocked that non-compete agreements are completely enforceable in Texas.