Global Financial Risk Factors and Sovereign Risk

Lambert here: Of course, there’s no sovereign risk for the United States.

By Simon Gilchrist, Professor of Economics, New York University, Bin We, Financial Economist and Adviser, Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta, Vivian Yue, Professor of Economics, Emory University, and Egon Zakrajšek
Senior Adviser, Bank for International Settlements; CEPR Research Fellow. Originally published at VoxEU.

The interconnections between the balance sheet of a sovereign and those of global financial institutions can lead to a widening of sovereign spreads unrelated to country-specific fundamentals. This column explores this financial-sovereign risk nexus and documents that a substantial portion of the co-movement among sovereign spreads can be accounted for by changes in global financial risk. Specifically, an increase in global financial risk causes a large and persistent widening of sovereign spreads, with the spillover effects especially pronounced for speculative-grade sovereign debt.

The decades following the liberalisation of the banking industry in the US and Europe in the 1990s – a period featuring numerous domestic and cross-border bank mergers, a rapid pace of financial innovation, and an explosion of international linkages – also saw large fluctuations in sovereign yield spreads. The large swings in sovereign spreads were frequently synchronous, as spreads rose and fell in tandem across different economies. Such co-movements can arise from common shocks to the economic fundamentals of the issuing countries, which affect the expected losses from a default, as well as from shocks that impact the investors’ valuations of sovereign debt. Among past columns on the Vox, Levy Yeyati and Williams (2010) study how global shocks – namely, changes in the US yield curve – drive sovereign spreads of emerging market economies. Daehler et al. (2020) examine the role of country-specific fundamentals.

In this column, we explore the interplay between sovereign and global financial risk and document that a substantial portion of the observed co-movement between sovereign spreads since the mid-1990s can be accounted for by financial risk factors, closely related to the risk appetite of global financial institutions. Global financial institutions such as large capital markets banks play a critical role in underwriting sovereign bonds to meet the demands of borrowing countries, as well as intermediating in the secondary markets where these securities are traded (Gennaioli et al. 2014, Morelli et al. 2021). Sharp moves in asset prices – unrelated to country-specific fundamentals – can significantly affect these institutions’ collateral values and true mark-to-market losses. The resulting concerns about solvency can reduce their risk-bearing capacity or appetite, leading to a synchronous repricing of sovereign debt and other risky assets, an onset of a ‘risk-off’ sentiment in popular parlance.

In a recent paper (Gilchrist et al. 2021), we formally analyse this sovereign-financial risk nexus using two measures of global financial risk: the ‘excess bond premium’ (EBP) of Gilchrist and Zakrajšek (2012) and the global financial cycle (GFC) factor of Miranda-Agrippino and Rey (2020). As argued by Gilchrist and Zakrajšek (2012), the EBP – a US corporate bond credit spread net of default risk – provides a measure of the risk appetite among bank-affiliated dealers, institutions that play a crucial role in the pricing of most credit-related assets that are actively traded. The GFC factor proposed by Miranda-Agrippino and Rey (2020), by contrast, is a latent factor that explains a significant portion of the variation in risky asset prices on a global scale.

Figure 1 shows these two financial risk factors – standardised for the ease of comparison – since January 1990. In addition to being positively correlated, both series are clearly countercyclical, rising sharply in periods of widespread financial distress.

Figure 1 Global financial risk factors

Source: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System; Miranda-Agrippino and Rey (2020).

To empirically examine how fluctuations in these two risk factors affect the dynamics of sovereign credit spreads, we construct a panel of dollar-denominated sovereign bonds traded in the secondary market. The panel contains nearly 1,800 individual securities issued by 53 countries, for which market prices were available during the 1995-2020 period. The two panels of Figure 2 display key features of these data: the central tendency of country-level credit spreads at each month-end, the median, and the corresponding cross-sectional dispersion of spreads, as measured by the interquartile range. Panel (a) focuses on bonds issued by countries having an investment-grade rating, while panel (b) covers countries rated as speculative grades.

Figure 2 Sovereign bond credit spreads

Note: The solid line in each panel shows the cross-sectional median of credit spreads on dollar-denominated sovereign bonds at month-end, while the shaded bands denote the corresponding interquartile ranges (i.e., Pctl75 – Pctl25).
Source: Refinitiv Eikon; authors’ calculations.

The substantial degree of dispersion in credit spreads across countries, in both segments of the market, indicates that country-specific factors are an important determinant of sovereign spreads at each point time. The role of financial risk factors is best seen by focusing on the years immediately preceding the 2008-09 financial crisis. The financial crisis is characterised by hefty risk appetite and buoyant investor sentiment, as evidenced by the unusually strong compression of sovereign spreads, in terms of both their levels and dispersion. As the cascade of shocks that roiled financial markets in 2008 eroded the confidence of investors and banks’ counterparties and seriously challenged the solvency of highly interconnected global financial institutions, sovereign credit spreads – concomitantly with the substantial increases in the EBP and the GFC factor – blew out across the credit-quality spectrum.

But do fluctuations in these financial risk factors influence the dynamics of sovereign spreads more generally? And if so, how persistent are their effects? To answer these questions, we use panel local projection methods to trace out the impact of shocks to the two financial risk factors on sovereign spreads, controlling for global, country-, and bond-specific determinants of spreads. Figure 3 plots the average response of the investment-grade and speculative-grade sovereign spreads to unanticipated shocks of one standard deviation to the EBP (panels (a) and (b)) and the GFC factor (panels (c) and (d)), respectively. The two shocks are, by construction, uncorrelated with the contemporaneous movements in the standard global factors that can drive sovereign spreads, as well as with country- and bond-specific controls.1

Figure 3 The impact of global financial risk on sovereign bond credit spreads

Note: The solid lines in panels (a) and (b) show the estimated responses of sovereign credit spreads to a one standard deviation orthogonalized shock to the EBP, while the solid lines in panels (c) and (d) show the responses of sovereign credit spreads to a one standard deviation orthogonalized shock to the GFC. The shaded band in each panel denotes the associated 90% confidence interval.
Source: Gilchrist et al. (2021).

An unanticipated one-time increase in the EBP of one standard deviation (roughly 25 basis points) has little effect on sovereign spreads upon impact, but the effect increases notably as the horizon grows (top row). For both investment-grade and speculative-grade sovereign spreads, the peak response occurs about 12 months after the impact of the EBP shock. In the case of investment-grade sovereign bonds, spreads widen about five basis points 12 months after the shock, whereas speculative-grade spreads increase about 15 basis points. It is worth noting that these peak responses are statistically different from zero at conventional significance levels and that their magnitudes are comparable to the responses of US corporate bond spreads to similarly identified EBP shocks documented in previous research.

A one standard deviation shock to the GFC factor, by contrast, has an economically large and statistically significant effect on sovereign spreads only in the near term, as the peak response in both segments of the market occurs within the first three months after the shock (bottom row). Note that the near-term economic effects of shocks to the GFC factor are comparable to the peak responses of spreads in the wake of the EBP shock. All told, our analysis indicates that a sudden onset of a risk-off sentiment – triggered by a reduction in the risk appetite of global financial institutions – leads to an economically significant and persistent widening of sovereign credit spreads, especially for riskier countries.

Motivated by this empirical evidence, we develop a theoretical framework, featuring linkages between the total intermediation capacity of the financial sector and sovereign debt risk premiums. In the model, the country’s choice of whether to default is endogenous, while the risk-bearing capacity of banks is governed by the tightness of their value-at-risk constraint as in Shin (2012). A tightening of this constraint – say, in response to an increase in aggregate uncertainty – reduces the risk appetite of the financial sector, forcing banks to deleverage and shrink their portfolios of sovereign bonds. The deleveraging pushes up the risk premium on sovereign bonds, inducing a significant widening of spreads. The rise in spreads boosts governments’ borrowing costs, which increases sovereign default risk, causing a further widening of sovereign spreads and a tightening of the banks’ value-at-risk constraint.

All told, we show that a substantial portion of the co-movement between sovereign credit spreads since the mid-1990s is accounted for by fluctuations in global financial risk. These effects are more pronounced and persistent when we measure global financial risk using the excess bond premium, a proxy for the risk appetite of major broker-dealers that are key players in the U.S. corporate bond market. Given the important role of global banks in today’s financial system, our theoretical framework also offers a useful perspective through which to view financial market disruptions that occurred in March 2020 with the onset of the Covid-19 pandemic (e.g. Moench et al. 2021).

Authors’ note: The views expressed are our own and do not necessarily reflect those of the Bank for International Settlements or the Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta.

References available at the original.

Print Friendly, PDF & Email

This entry was posted in Banking industry, Currencies, Europe, Globalization, Macroeconomic policy, Market inefficiencies on by .

About Lambert Strether

Readers, I have had a correspondent characterize my views as realistic cynical. Let me briefly explain them. I believe in universal programs that provide concrete material benefits, especially to the working class. Medicare for All is the prime example, but tuition-free college and a Post Office Bank also fall under this heading. So do a Jobs Guarantee and a Debt Jubilee. Clearly, neither liberal Democrats nor conservative Republicans can deliver on such programs, because the two are different flavors of neoliberalism (“Because markets”). I don’t much care about the “ism” that delivers the benefits, although whichever one does have to put common humanity first, as opposed to markets. Could be a second FDR saving capitalism, democratic socialism leashing and collaring it, or communism razing it. I don’t much care, as long as the benefits are delivered. To me, the key issue — and this is why Medicare for All is always first with me — is the tens of thousands of excess “deaths from despair,” as described by the Case-Deaton study, and other recent studies. That enormous body count makes Medicare for All, at the very least, a moral and strategic imperative. And that level of suffering and organic damage makes the concerns of identity politics — even the worthy fight to help the refugees Bush, Obama, and Clinton’s wars created — bright shiny objects by comparison. Hence my frustration with the news flow — currently in my view the swirling intersection of two, separate Shock Doctrine campaigns, one by the Administration, and the other by out-of-power liberals and their allies in the State and in the press — a news flow that constantly forces me to focus on matters that I regard as of secondary importance to the excess deaths. What kind of political economy is it that halts or even reverses the increases in life expectancy that civilized societies have achieved? I am also very hopeful that the continuing destruction of both party establishments will open the space for voices supporting programs similar to those I have listed; let’s call such voices “the left.” Volatility creates opportunity, especially if the Democrat establishment, which puts markets first and opposes all such programs, isn’t allowed to get back into the saddle. Eyes on the prize! I love the tactical level, and secretly love even the horse race, since I’ve been blogging about it daily for fourteen years, but everything I write has this perspective at the back of it.

5 comments

  1. Louis Fyne

    Of course there is no sovereign risk for the US. But the universe doesn’t give free lunches.

    In exchange for no US sovereign risk, the deal with the devil is increased risk for inflation. If people outside the US dump USD for something else, USAians pay more at the pump, bread aisle, and MegaLo Mart.

    MMT can cause inflation. But the theoretical point of MMT induced inflation is that it is redistributive, diluting the wealth of the top 0.5% and sending real wealth to the bottom 85%. but only if the needle is threaded right.

    but given the power systems, we will never see that. MMT will always be coopted by Beltway NyC

  2. Dave in Austin

    This article interests me because I guess I’ve always assumed the two factors were connected without even considering the possibility that they were unconnected. For me it was like “War leads to a flight to safety”- obvious.

    But I come from an international relations background and see financial changes as being caused by the internantional situation. I’m glad you’ve posted something on this so now my unconscious assumptions have been made consious. That’s education.

  3. Bellatrix

    “Of course, there’s no sovereign risk for the United States.”

    Personally, I would have added an emoji at the end of that sentence, just for clarity. Maybe “tongue-in-cheek”, “looking-to-heaven”, “rolling-your-eyes”, “pissing-yourself-laughing”, something like that.

  4. Sound of the Suburbs

    Why have we got such a fragile financial system that is so prone to collapse?
    We have no idea how the banking and monetary systems actually work.

    Rolling neoliberalism out globally has been a great opportunity to find out how the monetary system works.
    The financial crises are actually the time when the big advances can be made, and there have been plenty of those. These are the keys to unlock the secrets of the monetary system.
    When you understand the monetary system, you can achieve financial stability.
    It’s not as hard as today’s central bankers make it look.

    When you understand the monetary system, you can achieve financial stability.
    The financial crises are actually the time when the big advances can be made, and they did it before after 1929
    Financial stability arrived in the Keynesian era and was locked into the regulations of the time.
    https://www.brettonwoodsproject.org/wp-content/uploads/2009/10/banking-crises.png
    “This Time is Different” by Reinhart and Rogoff has a graph showing the same thing (Figure 13.1 – The proportion of countries with banking crises, 1900-2008).

    We removed the regulations, and put central bankers in charge, and the financial crises have come back.
    The central bankers are desperately trying to rediscover the secrets of financial stability.
    We have worked it out again, and are waiting to be consulted.

    1. Sound of the Suburbs

      Maybe they don’t know where I live.
      I live in a three bed semi on the outskirts of London.
      The helicopters should start landing in my back garden pretty soon
      One at a time please, my garden isn’t that big.

Comments are closed.