Collateral Damage From Higher Interest Rates

Yves here. Servaas Storm has produced yet another important paper, and relates post, on why the current conventional wisdom about how to deal with the current inflation, which is jack up interest rates until they kill demand stone cold dead, is destructive.

In this very accessible piece, Storm describes how establishment opinion, with Larry Summers its leading advocate, starts with the wrong-headed premise that the world needs Volcker 2.0. Without getting to the question of whether Volcker’s program was excessive, Storm describes how our current inflation is clearly not due to wage pressures, since workers have been generally losing or barely holding ground in real income terms.

Higher interest rates will be particularly disastrous for emerging economies which have high “sacrifice ratios” (the GDP cost of interest rate increases) and could kick off widespread debt crises.

Storm also points out that economists have falsely told politicians and the public that they only have two choices: big interest rate hikes now or a long period of high-ish interest rates. Storm argues that monetary policy is not a very good tool for our current tsuris and lists other possible approaches.

Sadly, it is apparently verboten in polite economic circles to discuss the elephant in the room: how sanctions against Russia are turbo-charging energy and commodities inflation (particularly agriculture products, which will show up more acutely in 2023) and finding a way to climb off that limb might be a good idea.

By Servaas Storm, Senior Lecturer of Economics, Delft University of Technology. Originally published at the Institute of New Economic Thinking website

For a long time, stagflation was thought to be a thing of the past. But now there is a real risk of it coming back, warns the Bank for International Settlements (BIS 2022), the ‘central bank’ for the world’s central banks. High inflation is expected to be around for a prolonged period of time—as a result of the recurring reinstatements of lockdowns in China, the surge in global energy and commodity prices following Russia’s war in Ukraine, global warming, and the breakdown of global supply chains due to geopolitical tensions.

High inflation, wars in key commodity-producing regions, slowing economic growth, tightening monetary policy and turbulence in commodity stock markets resemble the dominant features of the global economy in the 1970s (UNCTAD 2022; World Bank 2022). “That period ended in the early 1980s,” as Martin Wolf (2022) reminds us, “with a brutal monetary tightening in the U.S., a sharp reduction in inflation, and a wave of debt crises in developing countries, especially in those of Latin America.” This much is true: the collateral damage to the world economy of monetary tightening by the Fed included a lost decade for development in most Latin American and African economies.

No one wants a repeat of this disastrous episode—more so now, right after the worst global recession in 90 years, in which more than 114 million jobs were lost, the cumulative (confirmed) global death toll due to COVID-19 is more than 6.5 million persons (and counting), and about 120 million people were thrown back into extreme poverty. The COVID-19 recession affected the most vulnerable segments of societies disproportionately hard, as the highly uneven fiscal response to the pandemic widened already yawning disparities and inequities within and between countries (United Nations 2021). Higher spending on social protection and pandemic relief and lower revenues from taxation led to higher public budget deficits everywhere, and public debts rose significantly. The average public debt to GDP ratio for emerging economies in 2020 was 64% in 2020, up from an average value of 52% during 2015-19. IMF (2022a) forecasts suggest that the public debt to GDP ratio in emerging countries will rise even further—to 74% in 2026. The higher indebtedness comes with greater vulnerabilities to financial shocks, including higher interest rates.

Soft Versus Hard Landing

Nevertheless, support for a drastic monetary tightening in response to the rise in inflation during 2021-22 is growing in the U.S. and Europe. The most outspoken advocate of Volcker-like monetary tightening is Lawrence Summers (2022) who argues that “The US may need as severe monetary tightening as Paul Volcker pushed through in the late 1970s early 1980s.” Summers claims that the Federal Reserve may have to hike interest rates above 5% to beat back inflation, warning that if the Fed eases up in its inflation fight, this would be a “prescription for much higher interest rates and a sustained and very difficult stagflation that would have serious global consequences.”

No one doubts that further monetary tightening by the Fed will push the U.S. and the global economy into a recession. But opinions are divided over how deep and long-lasting the unavoidable recession will be. Establishment opinion is that “the time to throttle an inflationary upsurge is at its beginning, when expectations are still on the policymakers’ side,” as Wolf (2022) puts it. That is, the sooner and the more aggressive central bankers act, the lower will be the collateral damage to the (global) economy and the more likely the (global) economy will experience a ‘soft landing’.

The Bank for International Settlements (BIS 2022, p. 24) similarly warns, in its Annual Economic Report of 2022, that “the most pressing challenge for central banks is to restore low and stable inflation without, if possible, inflicting serious damage to the economy”, adding that “calibrating the response naturally involves a trade-off. Tightening too much and too quickly could inflict unnecessary damage. But doing too little would raise the prospect of a larger and more costly tightening down the road.” Establishment opinion firmly holds that it will be better to err on the ‘safe’ side—meaning that it is preferable to pre-emptively raise interest rates sooner and more aggressively, at the cost of a temporary and limited recession now, than to act more cautiously and risk inflation spiraling out of control, which would need much more strongly tightening later on and, hence, lead to a deeper and more prolonged recession (or worse).

This establishment opinion is urged upon central bankers in emerging and developing economies (EMDEs). For example, “a key lesson from the 1970s is,” according to World Bank (2022, p. 64), “that central banks need to act in a pre-emptive manner to avoid a loss of confidence in their commitment to maintaining low inflation [….] and to prevent a de-anchoring of inflation expectations.” For BIS (2022, p. 26), the task for central bankers is equally clear:

“The new inflationary environment has changed the balance of risks. Gradually raising policy rates at a pace that falls short of inflation increases means falling real interest rates. This is hard to reconcile with the need to keep inflation risks in check. Given the extent of the inflationary pressure unleashed over the past year, real policy rates will need to increase significantly in order to moderate demand. Delaying the necessary adjustment heightens the likelihood that even larger and more costly future policy rate increases will be required, particularly if inflation becomes entrenched in household and firm behavior and inflation expectations.” (Italics added).

A New INET Working Paper

One big problem with the establishment view is that it narrows down the public debate on policy responses to the rise in global inflation to a choice from a reductionist menu of only two options: (1) a fast and aggressive hike in interest rates, which is argued to lead to an unavoidable but mild and temporary recession (the soft-landing option) versus (2) a slower and more cautious monetary tightening that arguably can only end in tears (the hard-landing option). Framed in this way, the policy choice for central bankers is straightforward—but in my opinion, the above reductionist framing is wrong, as I argue in a new INET Working Paper, which served as a background paper for UNCTAD’s Trade and Development Report 2022.

First, there is a real risk that the global recession triggered by a fast and aggressive hike in interest rates in the U.S. and the E.U. (option 1) will permanently scar the process of economic growth and development in the EMDEs, leading to another ‘lost decade’. One reason why this may happen is the very high ‘sacrifice ratio’ of monetary policy, which reflects the collateral damage, defined in terms of the decline in real GDP, that is associated with the degree of monetary tightening needed to reduce the inflation rate by one percentage point as I argue below. A second reason concerns the negative distributional consequences of higher interest rates (in combination with austerity), which by hurting domestic demand growth and capital accumulation will not just lower potential growth in the EMDEs, but also reduce the size of serviceable debt in the economy. Finally, excessive monetary tightening may well lead to financial instability and crises in the EMDEs, given the already high public and private debts in many of these economies (Chowdhury and Jomo 2022). Simplistic calls to ‘bring back Volcker’ are dangerous and wrong because drastic monetary tightening is likely to bring about the exact stagflation that it is arguably intended to avoid. This would represent an epic failure of macroeconomic policymaking—even against its already highly checkered history.

There is a second reason why the reductionist framing is wrong: the policy choice is not a binary one and also does not just concern monetary policy. Establishment macroeconomics exclusively prioritizes monetary policy as the means to manage demand and the economy, downgrading all other policy tools (including fiscal policy instruments) to useless paraphernalia (Storm 2021). But drastically higher interest rates cannot and will not succeed in lowering current inflation, the origins of which lie mostly on the supply side (Storm 2022), at a bearable societal cost. In other words, a single-minded reliance on monetary tightening must end in tears, squeezing demand and lowering (potential) output, but failing to reduce inflation.

The good news is that governments have other policy instruments at their disposal which can be used to fight inflation and effectively manage its (distributional) consequences at lower economic and social cost than that associated with monetary tightening. Hence, to avoid another era of stagflation, it is now time to bring monetary policy down from its high pedestal, while the roles of fiscal policy (including income support), strategic price policy and stricter (financial) market regulation are in urgent need of a re-appreciation.

Key Lessons

This article presents key insights from the Working Paper, which center around the huge, and avoidable, economic and social, cost of an uncoordinated global monetary tightening led by the Federal Reserve, and point to the importance of trying out alternative interventions to bring down and manage (global) inflation. The Working Paper focuses on 11 major EMDEs (Argentina, Brazil, Chile, China, Egypt, India, Indonesia, Mexico, Nigeria, South Africa, and Türkiye)—and highlights the risks of non-coordinated interest rate hikes in these EMDEs in the context of monetary and fiscal policy tightening in the OECD.

No doubt, a drastic tightening of U.S. monetary policy will lead to currency depreciations, sudden financial outflows, higher risk premia, weaker credit positions, and more difficult access to global dollar credit and liquidity (necessary for exports and investment) in most EMDEs. Higher interest rates in the U.S. will thus stymie growth in emerging economies and further constrain their macroeconomic policy space (UNCTAD 2022), which was already compromised by rising commodity prices and the pandemic (Bortz et al. 2021). The ability of central banks in generally highly-indebted emerging economies to manage the fall-out of monetary tightening by the Federal Reserve will critically depend on their access to U.S. dollars—and this will depend on the Fed. A global recession, in turn, will hurt the US economy. Hence, clockwise or counter-clockwise, the Federal Reserve will have to balance its de jure national mandate and its de facto global function. The Fed cannot, therefore, act in ‘splendid isolation,’ also if it is narrowly considering the interests of the U.S. economy.

UNCTAD (2022, p. 22) is right in sounding the alarm that “it is not obvious [….] that tighter monetary and fiscal policies [in developed countries] are the correct response to inflation driven by supply-side bottlenecks”, because these policies “may have disastrous repercussions for developing countries if it triggers appreciation of the dollar.” With rising inflation, tightening monetary and financial conditions, and elevated debt levels considerably limiting policy space, emerging economies are facing increasingly stronger stagflationary headwinds (World Bank 2022). However, drawing historical parallels between the current inflation and the stagflation of the 1970s is not helpful: the differences are more important than the similarities.

There Is No Wage-Price Spiral in the EMDEs

Unlike in the 1970s, after decades of labor market deregulation and union bashing, workers across the globe are relatively powerless and incapable of protecting their real wages in this inflationary era (ILO 2021). This shows up in the secular decline in the labor income share and in declining real wages in the EMDEs (UNCTAD 2022). I must note that, in the EMDEs, the decline in worker power in the developing world has gone hand in hand with the growth and deepening of global supply chains, largely under the control of globe-spanning multinational corporations—usually headquartered in the triad (United States, Western Europe, and Japan). These multinationals have the power to impose strict cost and delivery conditions and often unreasonable demands for flexibility upon their suppliers, through which they have managed to exploit the workforce, disempower governments, undermine regulation, and to extract maximum value through a process of unequal exchange (Suwandi 2019).

As is shown in Figure 1, real wages in Brazil declined by more than 13% between September 2020 and April 2022, even if nominal wages rose by 3.3%. The drastic fall in real wages, which is observed for other EMDEs as well, shows that workers are bearing the brunt of the higher prices. Global inflation, fuelled by higher prices for food and energy, is eroding wages and pushing millions of people into poverty and hunger.

Sources: Monthly earnings: Instituto Brasileiro de Geografia e Estatística (IBGE); CPI: FRED database (series BRACPIALLMINMEI). Note: Monthly nominal wages are deflated using the monthly CPI.

It is evident that inflation in the EMDEs is not being driven by a wage-price spiral. World Bank (2022) and BIS (2022) are nevertheless calling for monetary tightening and fiscal retrenchment. These ‘medicines’ will be worse than the ‘disease’ (inflation), because they will lower employment and economic growth, and thus further increase the misery of workers, many of whom will become unemployed. “The misery of being exploited by capitalists is nothing compared to the misery of not being exploited all,” is how Joan Robinson (1962, p. 45) summarized the problem.

High Sacrifice Ratios

Implicit in the analyses of the World Bank (2022) and BIS (2022) is the assumption that interest rate increases will be effective in bringing accelerating inflation down to its target rate. As a truism, this assumption is correct: if central banks raise interest rates brutally enough, aggregate demand will be asphyxiated, the economy concerned will go into recession and inflation will be brought down. But the collateral damage of this kind of inflation control will be large, both in the short run in terms of higher unemployment and increased poverty and in the long run, because the damage done in the short run will spill over into permanent, long-run damage: the monetary policy error may cause business investment and, hence, the growth rate of potential output to decline (Kahn 1972).

Hence, the real question is whether monetary tightening can safely bring down inflation, i.e., without generating prohibitively high economic and social damages. The empirical evidence for emerging economies suggests that a soft landing is unlikely to be possible. Table 1 summarizes published evidence, mostly provided by central bank economists, on the responses of the inflation rate and real GDP to a one-percentage-point hike in the policy interest rate in Brazil, China, India, Mexico, Nigeria, and South Africa. The evidence is summarized in terms of the cumulative impacts after four quarters (one year) and eight quarters (two years).

It can be seen that the estimated impact of a one-percentage-point increase in the interest rate on the inflation rate is relatively small after four quarters—inflation in India, Nigeria, and South Africa is estimated to decline by just 0.1 percentage point; in Mexico, inflation declines by 0.5 percentage points in China and by 0.8 percentage points in Brazil.

The cumulative impacts on inflation are larger after two years, which indicates that monetary tightening works with considerable time lags. However, even after eight quarters, the cumulative effects of higher interest rates are estimated to be small relative to the current surge in inflation. Consider the case of South Africa where the CPI inflation rate (on a year-to-year basis) rose to 6.5% in May 2022. South Africa’s central bank sets the inflation target at 4.5% (with a tolerance margin of 1.5 percentage points on either side). Suppose we assume that the South African central bank decides to raise the interest rate in order to lower inflation by 2 percentage points from 6.5% to 4.5% over the next two years. To do so, it has to increase the interest rate by 4 percentage points—from 4.75% in May 2022 to 8.75%.

Sources: See Working Paper. Note: The ‘sacrifice ratio’ reflects the collateral damage, defined in terms of the decline in real GDP, that is associated with the degree of monetary tightening that is needed to reduce the inflation rate by one percentage point.

In sum, small increases in interest rates will not do enough to bring down demand and rising inflation in emerging economies in a significant way. Much higher increases in interest rate may work, but still take two years or more to make a dent in inflation—while also doing damage to real GDP.

The cumulative impact of a one-percentage-point increase in the interest rate on real GDP is considerably larger (in absolute terms) than on inflation (Table 1). The collateral damage of inflation control, which comes in the form of a recession and higher unemployment, is non-negligible. For example, an increase in the interest rate by 4 percentage points (as in the example for South Africa, mentioned earlier) will lower South Africa’s real GDP by 3.6 percentage points after two years, while Mexico’s real GDP will be depressed by 4 percentage points.

The cost of monetary tightening can be defined in terms of the ‘sacrifice ratio’, which gives the decline in real GDP that is associated with the degree of monetary tightening that is needed to reduce the inflation rate by one percentage point. The sacrifice ratio is around 2 for China, Mexico, and South Africa—meaning that a one-percentage-point reduction in the inflation rate comes at a social cost of (more than) a two-percentage-point decrease in real GDP. The ‘sacrifice ratio’ for India is estimated to equal 5.5.

Because bringing down inflation will require large increases in interest rates and since this will significantly depress real GDP, it follows that central banks in emerging countries cannot safelybring down inflation by means of monetary tightening. This outcome becomes even more likely in case of a simultaneous and uncoordinated monetary tightening by central banks in many emerging economies—Keynes’ fallacy of composition applies in this case, at a huge social cost to the populations of the EMDEs.

EMDEs Have Much Higher Debts Today

Another structural difference between the 1970s and the current conjuncture concerns the significantly higher indebtedness of emerging economies (Figure 2). In 1980, the total debt of the emerging market and developing economies (EMDEs) stood at 65% of their GDP, and half of this debt was sovereign debt and the other half was private-sector debt. When the U.S. Federal Reserve brutally tightened monetary policy in the late 1970s and early 1980s in response to rising inflationary pressures in the US, it triggered the ‘Third World’ debt crisis of the 1980s.

However, as Figure 2 illustrates, the initial conditions today are worse than in the 1980s with respect to external indebtedness. In 2020, after the largest, fastest, and most broad-based increase in indebtedness by the EMDEs in the past 50 years, total debt of the EMDEs amounted to 207% of their GDP. More than two-thirds of these debts are private-sector liabilities, while the share of public debt in total debt is 31%. Low global real interest rates during the 2010s encouraged a surge in EMDE debt, especially in Latin America and Sub-Saharan African countries. Much of these debts are denominated in foreign currency and are commercial and short-term. Many emerging economies are facing tighter financial conditions against a backdrop of high debt, and seventeen emerging and developing countries already experienced a downgrading of their sovereign debts in the first five months of 2022. Monetary tightening by the Federal Reserve thus carries a considerable risk of triggering a new domino chain of financial crises in the EMDEs (World Bank 2022).

Source: World Bank (2022), Figure SF1.5.A. Note: GDP-weighted averages based on a sample of up to 153 emerging market and developing economies.

China’s domestic debt warrants separate consideration for two reasons. Firstly, because total non-financial sector debt has almost doubled between 2008 and 2022Q3 (Figure 3); China’s total debt-to-GDP ratio increased from around 140% in 2008 to 274% in 2022Q3. Secondly, because the high debts of households and local governments are becoming increasingly difficult to service and a Chinese debt crisis is becoming more likely.

Let us first look at Chinese household debt which has more than doubled (as a percentage of GDP) since 2012. Servicing these household debts is eating up disposal income that could otherwise be used to buy goods and services, and, hence, high household indebtedness, combined with rising interest rates, is undermining consumer demand and economic growth. Chinese households increased borrowing mainly to purchase houses (apartments), mostly in presale transactions—purchases of properties not yet built. Rising house prices and low interest rates made this possible during 2010-2020. But in 2020, the Chinese government began to slow down the property sector, whose ballooning levels of debt were worrying officials.

China’s property sector has been cooling down rapidly in 2022, following the corona lockdowns and Zero-COVID policies, economic stagnation, and rising interest rates. The Chinese property market went into freefall, and developers slashed purchases of land. All this has resulted in a liquidity crunch for Chinese property developers, as presale receipts plummeted and access to bank financing became increasingly difficult (IMF 2022b). The near-default of China Evergrande Group, one of China’s largest property developers, in Spring 2021 is all too well known. In effect, prices for new homes are falling in 70 major cities, some 2 million off-plan homes, presold to Chinese households, remain unfinished across the country, and Xi Jinping’s government is forced to bail out the property market in an attempt to prevent a financial-sector crisis (Farrer 2022).

Source: National Institution for Finance & Development; http://www.nifd.cn/Home/IndexEn

Chinese central government debt has increased from 28% of GDP in 2008 to almost 50% of GDP in 2022Q3. But the Chinese state has a far larger debt burden than this, because hidden local government debt, which is included in the debt of the non-financial corporate sector (in Figure 3), has increased to more than 50% of GDP by 2021. Worryingly, most of China’s local government debt is held by off-balance-sheet state-owned or state-controlled financial institutions, called local government financing vehicles (LGFVs).

Many of these borrowings by LGFVs, which are estimated to amount to $8 trillion, are not recorded and transparency is weak when it comes to how the funds are used. The LGFVs financed their investment in local government debts by issuing bonds, which are now at risk of defaulting amid the building crash in China’s residential property market (Farrer 2022).

The problem is that local governments are heavily reliant on the revenues from land sales to balance their books, but Chinese property developers drastically lowered their purchases of land. As local government revenues began to dry up, the ability to service LGFV debt weakened. The housing bubble and the land market boom threaten to spill over into a public debt crisis. It is, as yet, unclear how Xi’s government will tackle the unavoidable LGFV debt crisis.

Macroeconomically, a total (consolidated) debt of the Chinese state is around 100% of Chinese GDP, and higher interest rates will hurt China’s public finances—as in Brazil and India. Fiscal austerity will augment the insufficiency of aggregate demand and slow down economic growth. The resulting economic stagnation, in turn, will make a (public and/or private) debt crisis more likely.

Alternatives to Monetary Tightening

The Working Paper discusses the likelihood of contractionary devaluations in the developing world—and argues, based on a review of the empirical evidence on the effectiveness of monetary policy in lowering inflation in the EMDEs, that central banks cannot bring down current inflation without engendering considerable damage to their economies. A ‘soft landing’ is an impossibility, so the economic policy discussion should focus on the issue of whether a ‘hard landing’—a deep and prolonged recession caused by monetary tightening—is a social cost worth suffering in order to bring down inflation.

In my view, given the significant (and avoidable) collateral damage caused by monetary tightening (measured in terms of output losses, increased unemployment, much higher inequality, and significantly greater and deeper poverty), hiking up interest rates is not a rational policy response to the recent surge in inflation—and this conclusion becomes even more weighty when one considers the risk that excessive monetary tightening leads to ‘super-hysteresis’, i.e., permanent damage to the level and the growth rate of an economy’s potential output.

Lord Kahn (1972, p. 139) issued this prophetic warning against restrictive monetary policy in his evidence given to the Radcliffe Committee on Monetary Reform in 1958:

“The economic waste in such a policy is particularly great if demand is regulated by restricting productive investment, as will be the main result of relying on monetary policy. Not only is there a loss of potential investment. But the growth of productivity is thereby curtailed, thus narrowing the limit on the permissible rate of rise in wages and increasing the amount of unemployment required to secure observance of the limit.” (Italics added).

Kahn warned against regulating aggregate demand, and business investment in particular, by means of monetary policy. The reason is that monetary tightening will raise the ‘steady-inflation’ rate of unemployment and, therefore, the unemployment gap—the difference between the (lowered) actual and the (heightened) ‘steady-inflation’ unemployment rate—rises as well. Higher interest rates are hurting potential real GDP by lowering endogenous demand-led productivity growth and by raising the inflation barrier, defined in terms of the ‘steady-inflation’ rate of unemployment.

If further monetary tightening in the US during 2022-23 triggers a worse global recession than the one occurring during the early 1980s, the potential growth rate in the developing economies will take a hit—and the permanent damage to economic development in these countries will be large. This permanent scarring of potential growth, in turn, will have dire implications for developing countries’ indebtedness: the volume of supportable (or serviceable) debt must decrease. The risk of another, avoidable, round of EMDE’s debt crises increases—and another ‘decade lost to economic development’ is in the cards, if the current phase of monetary tightening goes too far.

It is, therefore, critically important to consider alternative ways to bring inflation down. The final section of the Working Paper discusses a few such options, including the much-maligned strategic price controls, a tightening of position limits and an increase in margin requirements to eliminate commodity-market speculation, and fiscal interventions to shield vulnerable households and firms from the negative impacts of high inflation.

Finally, I discuss the importance of (external) debt relief measures and of reforms to improve the access of developing economies to global U.S. dollar liquidity. These alternatives, in turn, have to be embedded in a larger, more ambitious reform of the global financial system that supports stable exchange rates, long-run ‘committed’ finance, steered toward productive economic activities (rather than toward speculative returns), and open, but managed and sustainable international trade, while ensuring sufficient (fiscal) policy autonomy for developing nations to raise living standards and expand life opportunities for their citizens in low-carbon and socially-inclusive ways (Gallagher and Kozul-Wright 2022).

See original post for references

Print Friendly, PDF & Email

24 comments

  1. eg

    I have no doubt that Professor Storm is correct. I am also convinced that those responsible for US policy couldn’t be arsed.

    This is going to be disastrous.

  2. Patrick Donnelly

    We need to adopt the so far hidden technologies that can alter almost everything.

    To do this, we/they need to erase the dead hands that have insisted that their investments in obsolescent tech, pays off. To do that, we need disruption, inflation and collapses. This has taken longer to arrange than anticipated, but will be all the deeper as a result. Some who thought they were on the inside may now be panicking, but decay occurs elsewhere than just in old industries.

    Some glorious lies have been spun.

    Those who relied on them may fail badly. Others will do well. As usual, but not to this degree.

    Fiats that exceed the asset backing of say, 7 years GNP, will waste away, others will need to take measures else become like the Swiss Franc…

    Fictional Reserve theft may or may not disappear immediately after the crisis. Asset values and wages will reset. All those electronic and paper promises…? Hmmmm….. some will be honoured but most will not.

    No dramatic ‘Justice’ show trials… suicides, sadly, but co-operation will resume in most countries.

    Wealth is health and not being greedy, I am afraid. All that praise of greed and the goads of fear for the future will wither and people will slowly awaken.

    Some countries will be reorganized, voluntarily or else after threats and visits. The new tech will be rather too dangerous to allow wars over territory or oil

    1. Hickory

      Can someone drop a link to a resource that describes what the BIS actually does? I always hear it described the same way – central banks’ central bank – but without its own currency I don’t understand its role. Is it a lender of last resort somehow?

      Thanks

  3. Patrick Donnelly

    Growth is determined by statistics that measure what they can measure. With more deglobalization, the ’emerging economies’ will do just fine, even if the stats declare otherwise.

    The UK, which has way too many workers who are not European and not skilled, will decline further. ‘Services’, especially FIRE, will be devastated. We will miss them, right? Lots of statistical blood letting there!

  4. Mikel

    EMDEs..sounds like they need alternatives to running their economy that don’t involve borrowing from where they’ve been borrowing and a rethink of what they are doing with resources.
    They should probably kick a good number of NGOs to the curb too.

  5. Alice X

    What would Steve Keen have to say? De-growth I expect. We’re using 1.7 Earths and a huge reset is coming.

    1. Adam Eran

      JFYI, Warren Mosler (an MMT founder) says Volcker’s huge interest rate rise (21% prime loans, 16 – 18% mortgages) in the early eighties wasn’t what put an end to the inflation caused by OPEC restricting production. A barrel of oil cost $1.75 in 1971 — U.S. peak [pre-fracking] oil–and after quadrupling almost instantly, the price peaked at $42/bbl in 1982. The price rises for this critical commodity rippled throughout the U.S. economy in the ’70s.

      What did put an end to inflation? According to Mosler, it was Jimmy Carter deregulating natural gas. Producers won’t drill unless they know the well will pay off, so price rises in gas encouraged drilling for harder-to-get-gas, putting a damper on that shortage. The final nail in inflation’s coffin was Alaska’s North Slope coming online a bit later. The price retreated to around $10/bbl.

      Handling supply shortages by making money more expensive (i.e. raising rates) is probably an indication of clinical insanity.

  6. cnchal

    The simplest solution to inflation is to tax the shit out of the rich.

    Tax Summers up the wazoo so he can’t outbid me for a loaf of bread.

    1. spud

      you can try to tax the s##t out of them, but under free trade you will not get all that much. most of the money will go offshore in all sorts of ways. free trade has created a global oligarchy. institute protectionism, tariffs, capital controls etc,. and you will be able to get far far more out of them.

  7. spud

    summers and the fed knows this really has nothing to do with inflation, its all about reducing whats left of american labor, into accepting the standard of living of a asian garment worker.

    they know the inflation is coming from the results of free trade and a lack of democratic control of the markets.

    tim ryan of ohio who might eek by understands this, although i do not trust him.

    https://jacobin.com/2022/11/tim-ryan-jd-vance-ohio-congress-midterm-race

    “Ryan’s own district, Ohio’s Thirteenth, is in many ways a microcosm of the Midwest’s economic trajectory since NAFTA. In the decade following the agreement’s advent in 1993, almost a fifth of the state’s manufacturing businesses had shuttered. The Thirteenth was particularly hard hit. Youngstown, its biggest urban area, is one of the poorest cities in America, and today has a population some 60 percent lower than it had in 1930.

    Ryan’s response to these developments evinces a keener understanding of deindustrialization and its consequences than one typically sees from Democratic politicians. He’s shown a willingness to speak critically about globalization and even about America’s “broken economic system.”

    “We were always supposed to be the party of working people,” Ryan recently remarked of his own party. “And so those rank-and-file union members kept getting crushed, and jobs kept leaving, and their unions and the Democrats weren’t able to do anything for them.” Whatever else, he clearly grasps present-day realities of the American Midwest that the likes of Hillary Clinton and Chuck Schumer have not.”

    https://scheerpost.com/2022/11/02/democrats-are-ignoring-the-death-blow-to-the-middle-class/

    “Ohio Senate candidate Tim Ryan has been warning his fellow Democrats that the embrace of automation, free trade and globalization would cost them. Ryan lobbied Democrats for years to prioritize domestic manufacturing and re-training which would minimize some of the damage. But he was largely ignored.”

  8. chuck roast

    These monetary policies we have been using for 50 years were developed during the period of industrial capitalism and widespread organized labor…a tenuous combo that produced actual “things” for consumption. Industrial capitalism has disappeared along with organized labor…at least in the US. Is it any wonder that this crude, anachronistic monetary hammer no longer works in an age of finance capitalism where society is organized around the production and consumption of ever more debt? Little wonder, then, that the demand and consumption of increasingly scarce actual “things” can produce incessant price rises.

    We need a Ricardo vs. Malthus moment…after we euthanize the economists.

  9. YuShan

    Funny how during a decade of ZIRP/NIRP, nobody ever talked about the collateral damage from LOW interest rates. Many people on fixed incomes have been slaughtered.

    1. Milton

      Yeah but… I’m not seeing my 0.1% rate of return in my savings account getting any larger. At least with the 80s high rates, pass book savings returns were commensurate with the prime rate.

  10. aj

    While I think increasing prices (through interest rates) to combat increased prices (through inflation) is completely ridiculous, I think rates need to get back to a normal range of 3-5% and have been saying so for a while. What we saw during ZIRP were massive increases to asset prices, particularly stocks and housing as money had no safe way to earn low but steady returns.

    The vast amount of cheap money available to those who already had it lead to our current situation where new entrants can’t afford mortgages and the amount of real estate owned by corporate entities in order to charge rents (and AirBnB rentals) increased dramatically.

    While I think the link between interest rates and inflation/unemployment is sketchy at best, not having a safe form of interest income encourages stupid, risky activity. Now if the Fed keeps going into 1980’s rates, I’ll change my tune.

  11. Cetra Ess

    Agree with eg’s comment that those responsible for American policy couldn’t be arsed but I would go one step further and say their mentality towards the rest of the world and especially towards EMDE’s is that of plantation owner – they think of the slaves as less than human, incapable of managing let alone possessing money, and so will manage their finances for them.

    Thus collateral damage becomes quite acceptable and is deemed sometimes necessary, “for their own good”. Prof. Storms labeling it “collateral damage” probably outright sells monetary tightening to that particular audience.

    Side note: There’s a table on the wiki about Emerging Markets with about 10 different analysts including IMF and the BRICS and which countries they consider ’emerging’. If I’m interpreting it correctly, it’s interesting that the BRICS seem to assess fewer countries as emerging compared to other analysts. Meanwhile, the IMF includes the BRICS as emerging, of course, and I note Professor Storms seems to agree with most analysts in including Brazil and China in his assessment, I wondered why those two were singled out. Also, I learned Morgan Stanley (MSCI) does not consider Russia to be EMDE – the only other analyst in this regard. The reason I went looking was to see if there was a pattern based on skin color, though I wouldn’t be surprised if IMF in particular had color charts…

  12. Karl

    To discuss solutions to inflation and resulting high interest rates, please let’s start with the opening paragraph on root causes:

    High inflation is [a result of] lockdowns in China, … [the surge in] prices following Russia’s war in Ukraine, global warming, … and the breakdown of global supply chains due to geopolitical tensions.

    Some points:

    The rising dollar has the effect of keeping prices (and hence inflation) of goods imported from China by the US low. Lockdowns may stretch out delivery times but I doubt its a big driver of US inflation.

    This leaves:

    – “the surge in prices from Russia’s war in Ukraine.” Correction: economic sanctions on Russia.
    – “the breakdown of global supply chains due to geopolitical tensions”. Correction: US trade restrictions on various countries’ output, particularly China.
    – “global warming.” I’m not sure how global warming fits as a root cause of the momentary phenomenon of today’s inflation; it’s rather like attributing long term climate effects to today’s weather. So this factor seems overstated.

    A factor not identified is lagged effects of global supply disruptions and the sudden release of pent-up demand due to the relaxation of Covid lockdowns and Covid-related stimulus measures around the world 2020-2022. This root cause is probably pretty significant.

    The identified root causes in this article seem largely due to politically motivated punitive actions against other countries by the U.S. government.

    To the extent that Covid is a primary root cause, raising interest rates do not address this root cause either. They will lead to a lagged demand destruction probably at least comparable to whatever demand stimulus might have been passed earlier to deal with the political storms around Covid lockdowns. What the government “gave” in the past (stimulus checks), the government is now taking away (lost jobs and incomes due to higher interest rates). Both the “give” and the “take” effects have and will lead to greater deficits, given that a recession will lead to lower government revenues and higher counter-cyclical government spending at all (Fed/State/muni) levels.

    To the extent that these policies don’t really address root causes, and may actually make matters worse, our problems are traceable to our gerontocracy (Biden/Pelosi/Summers et. al.) that is still living in the Cold War era (Russia! China!) and the Volcker era.

    We will be stuck with them at least until 2024.

    1. Yves Smith Post author

      Global warming is a contributor due to poor crop yield/harvest shortfalls. Drought this summer led France, normally the world’s #4 grain exporter, to have very poor production.

      More generally:

      Despite important agricultural advancements to feed the world in the last 60 years, a new study shows that global farming productivity is 21% lower than it could have been without climate change. This is the equivalent of losing about seven years of farm productivity increases since the 1960s.

      https://woods.stanford.edu/news/seven-years-agricultural-productivity-growth-lost-due-climate-change

      And a few days ago:

      Changes to growing seasons, limitations on water rights and increasingly powerful storms are all forcing growers to consider whether to shut down, relocate or otherwise alter their operations. Extreme weather events are also disrupting the shipping of food across the country and world.

      These five crops tell the story of the havoc the climate crisis is already causing.

      https://www.theguardian.com/environment/2022/nov/01/climate-crisis-us-food-system-five-crops

      Rice and wheat, dietary staples, were on the list

  13. spud

    the author may not know it, but Storm is making a good argument against free trade.

    the founders warned against foreign entanglements, and they meant economic, as well as military.

    by gutting the sovereignty of nations, and turning over the control of the markets and economies over to the private sector, we used to call that fascism.

    when the worlds oligarchs(that were created by free trade)say this is how its gonna be, even though us little people know it will not work and make things worse, it gets done anyways. and i agree, i posted a while back ago that to raise interests rates slowly, when inflation was far higher, it still is cheaper to borrow.

    so rates got to go way higher than inflation right away. of course that will being on a instant depression, instead of the slow motion one we have now. and in the end, the inflation is still being caused by free trade and a lack of democratic control over the markets.

    keynes knew this,

    http://www.go2cio.com/articles/index.php?id=3668

    “The trouble with free trade, Keynes suggested, was the assumption “that if you throw men out of work in one direction you re-employ them in another. As soon as that link in the chain is broken the whole of the free trade argument breaks down.”

    “In a famous 1933 article entitled “National Self-Sufficiency,” Keynes continued on this theme, writing of his sympathy “with those who would minimise, rather than with those who would maximize, economic entanglements between nations. Ideas, knowledge, art, hospitality, travel-these are things which should of their nature be international. But let goods be homespun whenever it is reasonable and conveniently possible; and, above all, let finance be primarily national.”

  14. Robert

    The first order cause of price inflation is companies raising the price they charge customers. As a small business owner myself, I know that raising prices is always a business calculation based on profitability. Do I raise prices or increase production? Either one will increase profitability.

    All these pundits spouting their Eco 101 bunk about inflation always being a monetary phenomenon or its because citizens received a stimulus check are clueless card carrying members of the PMC. Unfortunately, companies with a strong market share have figured out that cutting production and raising prices is the most profitable of all. This unethical, damaging business choice hurts a lot of people and it’s why we’re seeing imassive price increase in fossil fuels and food, to name two.

Comments are closed.