The Impact of Brexit on the UK economy: Reviewing the Evidence

Conor here: The following piece looks at trade, migration and investment (as well as the overall macroeconomic impacts) in the post-Brexit UK, and the conclusions are sobering. With declining living standards and seemingly no political solution, how much longer will UK citizens maintain the stiff upper lip?

By Jonathan Portes, a professor of economics and public policy at King’s College London. Originally published at Vox EU.

One year ago, CEPR published a summary of the evidence on the economic impacts of Brexit on the UK economy (Portes 2022).  Since then, the British public appears to have made up its mind on this topic: two-thirds think Brexit has damaged the economy, while even among Leave voters only one in five think the impact has been positive (UK in a Changing Europe 2023). The vast majority of economists would agree (and many would add a resounding ‘we told you so’). But that does not mean that we fully understand how, and to what extent, Brexit has affected the UK economy.  In this column, I summarise the evidence across three key dimensions – trade, migration and investment – and then examine recent evidence on the overall macroeconomic impacts.

First, trade.  The most obvious and direct impact of Brexit was to reintroduce significant barriers to trade between the UK and its largest trading partner, so it’s here that the impacts should be the most salient. And indeed, the headline result is that the UK’s trade performance has suffered considerably. The Office for Budget Responsibility notes that the UK’s ‘trade intensity’ (trade as a proportion of GDP) has fallen significantly, and considerably more than other advanced economies (OBR 2023).

Most academic analysis suggests that Brexit is at least partly responsible. Using synthetic differences-in-differences, Du et al. (2023) find that Brexit has had a large and continuing negative impact on UK goods exports, with particularly large impacts on smaller firms.  Confirming this with more qualitative evidence, Bailey et al. (2023) find that the “imposition of new non-tariff barriers through Brexit has proved particularly challenging to smaller firms in manufacturing supply chains”.

However, Office for National Statistics trade data suggest that rather than seeing – as simple trade models of the impact of Brexit would imply – a sharp fall in our trade with the EU in both goods and services, goods trade has been weak across the board, while services trade has held up well (ONS 2023). Moreover, there is little evidence of a differential impact on UK exports to the EU compared to exports outside the EU (Freeman et al. 2022), although they also find that smaller firms have been more adversely affected.

There are plausible, but as yet unproven, explanations for this.  On the one hand, conventional trade models fail to take full account of how Brexit has impacted the UK’s participation in global supply chains (Baldwin 2014). On the other hand, strength in service exports reflects the UK’s strong position in high value sectors like consultancy where there are few barriers to trade and where the pandemic has actually helped normalise the remote delivery of services (Hale and Fry 2023) .  To further complicate the issue, there are numerous anomalies in the data. So while it’s reasonable to conclude that Brexit has damaged the UK’s trade performance, both the magnitude and the mechanisms remain open to question.

Second, immigration.  Again, the obvious and direct impact of Brexit was to end free movement, and there’s no doubt that has restricted labour supply – net immigration from the EU, which peaked at over 200,000 a year at the time of the referendum, is now negative. That in turn has had, as predicted, some negative impacts both on specific sectors and the flexibility of the UK labour market as a whole (Portes and Springford 2023).  The main impact has, again as predicted (Portes 2021), mostly been higher prices and reduced output in the affected sectors, rather than sharply higher wages. Indeed, it is notable that recent wage growth has actually been stronger is sectors such as finance than in sectors more directly affected by reduced migration flows (Bank of England 2023).

However, what was not predicted was the sharp rise in immigration from outside the EU, both for work and study, which – in numerical terms at least – has more than offset the reduction in EU migration.  This has been driven by a number of factors, especially the relative liberalism of the post-Brexit system, refugee flows, and growth in international students (UK in a Changing Europe 2023b).  While not all are strictly ‘Brexit impacts’,  this shift in both the nature and national origin of migrants is very much consistent with the stated objectives of the new system (Portes 2023a). From this perspective, the short-term economic damage seen in sectors currently undergoing a painful adjustment process to the end of free movement will be more than offset by the longer-term benefits of shifting towards more selective, higher-skilled migration.  While it’s too soon to tell whether these will materialise, again the picture is more nuanced than simply observing that Brexit has reduced migration from the EU.

Finally, investment. The relatively low level of business investment in the UK pre-dated Brexit, but both aggregate data and survey evidence strongly suggest that Brexit is at least in part responsible for the particularly poor performance since 2016, with investment perhaps 10% lower than it would otherwise have been. That in turn might translate to reduction in productivity, and hence output, of a little over 1% of GDP (Haskel and Martin 2023).  One key question here is whether this reduction reflects, at least in part, Brexit-related uncertainty, in which case some catch-up might be expected.

So, taking all this together, what’s the bottom line? First, the public is right. Brexit has damaged the UK economy. But, inevitably, the mechanisms and hence the impacts have been considerably more complex than economists could incorporate in macroeconomic or trade models, with their inevitably simplifying assumptions.   To simplify hugely, however, it would be reasonable to say that the impact on trade overall has been broadly consistent with predictions so far, that on immigration much less negative (and perhaps even positive) and on investment somewhat worse.

What does this mean for the UK economy overall? The best publicised estimate (Springford 2022) again uses a synthetic counterfactual methodology, very much following Campos et al. (2014), who used a similar method to estimate the (positive) impacts on UK GDP of EU membership. Springford finds a negative impact of about 5% since the vote to leave in 2016.  However, in a recent critique, Gudgin and Lu (2023) argue that “[Springford’s] CER doppelganger index does not provide a credible measure of the impact of Brexit”.

However, as I explain in Portes (2023b), not only is Gudgin and Lu’s critique far from convincing on theoretical grounds, their alternative approach – a simple error correction mechanism – actually produces results which are functionally identical to Springford’s, as the two figures below show.

Figure 1 UK GDP vs synthetic counterfactual (Springford/Centre for European Reform)

portes7julyfig1.jpg

Source: Springford (2022).

Figure 2 UK GDP vs ECM forecast (Gudgin and Lu methodology)

portes7julyfig2.jpg

Source: Gudgin and Lu (2023).

However, it is important to note that techniques like this, which rely essentially on quantitative estimates of the change in relative UK economic performance after the Brexit vote, can by definition only measure the change in UK growth after 2016 relative to other countries. They cannot measure why it changed.  While some or even most of that change may be attributable to Brexit, other factors – for example, as Gudgin and Lu argue, changes in US fiscal policy, or the acceleration of economic recovery in Greece – will also affect relative growth rates, as indeed will changes in the UK economic environment unrelated to Brexit. For example, the recent slowdown in UK labour supply growth is not primarily a Brexit phenomenon (OBR 2023).

It is also the case that UK growth performance in the period running up to the referendum compared well to that of other large European economies, and that the implicit assumption that this would have continued, absent Brexit, may well not be accurate. It seems likely that a substantial part but by no means all of the ‘underperformance’ – which, as Gudgin and Lu and others point out, is at least in part shared by some other large European countries – is unlikely to be the result of Brexit, and that both the estimates reported above are therefore too large.

Given this, it is helpful to supplement models such as those above with a qualitative description of other things that might have changed since 2016 to affect the UK’s relative growth trajectory, as well as comparing to ex ante estimates. For example, UK in a Changing Europe (2019) models the impacts of a potential ‘hard Brexit’ more or less along the lines of the actual Trade and Cooperation Agreement, combined with a relatively ‘liberal’ migration policy; in other words, something very similar to the actual policy outturn.  This suggested that the negative impact would be between roughly 2% and 6% of GDP, with the large range reflecting uncertainty about productivity impacts. So far, the picture painted above seems broadly consistent with our analysis.

Can we narrow down the range?  Given the UK’s poor investment performance, my judgement is that the upper end of that range seems more plausible, and – very roughly – perhaps half that impact has materialised so far, with the rest still to come though. My central view is therefore that the best estimate of the negative impact on Brexit on UK GDP to date is 2–3% of GDP.  But, as the discussion above shows, the debate is far from over.

Print Friendly, PDF & Email

11 comments

  1. The Rev Kev

    Excellant coverage but there might be another factor in play here. So here it is said-

    ‘Given the UK’s poor investment performance, my judgement is that the upper end of that range seems more plausible, and – very roughly – perhaps half that impact has materialised so far, with the rest still to come though. My central view is therefore that the best estimate of the negative impact on Brexit on UK GDP to date is 2–3% of GDP.’

    And I can see that to be true. But what really throws a spanner into any prediction is the current British leadership – or lack of. As an example, instead of cleaning house or instituting reforms, their main focus stays on the Ukraine ‘for as long as it takes.’ Everything else is secondary. If Starmer gets in, there will be very little difference in how the UK is being run. Professional commenters have used the word ‘stagnation’ but with pressure building up behind the scenes. So with the British leadership at the moment, that negative impact of 2–3% of GDP may turn out to be optimistic range.

    1. Jokerstein

      If Starmer gets in, there will be very little difference in how the UK is being run.

      Truly another “nothing will fundamentally change.” suit-filler.

    2. Fazal Majid

      I think Brexit is more a symptom of the same underlying root cause of British economic under-performance, namely the utter incompetence of its PPE-educated political elite (PPE=Philosopy, Politics and Economics, the university major of choice for tossers like Liz Truss).

      The UK is thought of as practicing capitalism as red in tooth and claw as the US, but it’s more useful to model it as a feudal state, starting with land ownership and the institution of leasehold, a legal system originally designed to bind serfs to the land. Everywhere you look, you can see it, from the supine way people here accept the £600M inheritance tax break given to Chuck the Third, or how taxes fall heavily on income but not at all on property that is held.

  2. spud

    brexit did not damage the U.K.’S economy, that was done by the free traders that destroyed the u.k.’s manufacturing, gutted unions, gutted internal supply chains, gutted their standard of living, and flooded the country with immigrants.

    basically the u.k. is a failed state, just as Sri Lanka, Pakistan, and the U.S., or any free trade country today are.

    both major parties in the u.k. just as in the u.s.a. are captured by free trade fundies, and brexit was handled poorly, and they are incompant to rule, just as in any state captured by the fundies.

    to rebuild will take decades, if ever from the carnage of free trade. it could be worse for the u.k., they could still be in the free trade E.U., i am sure the citizens of greece or italy would gladly trade places with u.k. citizens.

    1. digi_owl

      Pretty much. UK was bleeding out before they entered EU, and brexit just ripped out the EU IV that sustained London while the periphery was slowly succumbing to gangrene.

      Basically the nation grew far too big for its own good during the empire, and the government still think and behave as if they are one.

      1. Geoffrey

        Thats they way I see it too: UK’s current state is the end state of NeoLiberalism 1.0. As commentator Jack Rasmus has it opinion – or history – is still out on how ‘Neoliberalism 2.0’ will play out from here. According to Rasmus, NL 2.0 will entail the end of democracy – already mostly achieved – and a more oppressive state (wartime is a great excuse for the latter) to facilitate the capitalist class agenda.

        But Brexit can only be judged against the alternative scenario of the UK having remained in what is turning out to be an increasingly fractious and dysfunctional EU (to which UK is contributing in no small part by leading the charge in Ukr). One can only quote Gramscii on the old order being dead and the new one cannot yet be born; the interregnum will be most likely destructive and disorderly….

  3. Synoia

    the current British leadership – or lack of. As an example, instead of cleaning house or instituting reforms, their main focus stays on the Ukraine ‘for as long as it takes.

    Good analysis, but if the rich, the upper class, do dominate parliament as thy have for most of the UK history then this prevails “When in trouble at home go adventuring abroad.

    In addition the Labor party is a mere shadow of its working class power due to the continuing ebb of manufacturing in the UK.

    For example, Dyson’s factory in in Malaya – and as I recall the rational was that Dyson could not find a large enough site for his new factory. Or the old BMC factory in Swindon, which is now making parts for Japanese auto companies.

  4. Sunny Tzu

    I think the bottom line of this is the permanent unstability of Europe that the constellation of political macrostructures has not solved at all (if not worsened). I mean, EU, what is left of EFTA (EU members with privileges), and so on. The UK (elites) firstly didn’t want to access to EEC (France didn’t either), but US and (West) Germany did. It was needed a coup in France. The 1973 referendum was almost a reverse of the 2014 one.

    The critical point IMHO was the Troika’s treatment of Greece. It was so scandalous that what is left of working class in Britain became totally alienated about EU, and it was detected by some elites in Britain that they thought the UK would have more leverage, over the EU itself, outside than inside. They seized the “opportunity” and now they are in a pretty pool of shit.

    All about Europe (except Russia) is chaotic and managed by people with mental illnesses.

    1. Ridgewood

      The arguement goes that Brexit was only possible due to Gordon Brown’s insistence in keeping the pound sterling. Thus people in the UK could pretend their savings accounts were worth the same after exiting the oligarchic European Union.

      Want to swap Euro for Greek drachmas?

      Joke there.

  5. TKMAXX

    The doppelganger study is nothing more than a correlation. As Jonathan somewhat acknowledges, all it tells us is how does the UK compare against the UK’s performance trying to hold constant how other countries have performed… however, other countries are not the UK! They do not tell us anything about the counterfactual universe in which the UK remained in the EU! To put it formally, there are far too many endogenous variables in this model to draw any conclusion from how the overall UK economy has been affected.

    A better study would look at the differences between GB and NI; there, NI has remained part of the CU and SM for goods. This would be far more insightful

Comments are closed.