Action Delayed, Justice Denied by Voluntary ESG Approach

Yves here. This post provides a compact critique of the investment gimmick called “ESG” as in “Environment, Social and Governance”. Institutional investors, such as endowments and public pension funds, have fetishized ESG investing as a way to pretend to be more responsible capitalists.

In reality, only good governance, the “G” in ESG, regularly improves investment returns. There is evidence that some diversity on boards (like requiring at least one board member to be female) improves performance, but I don’t recall seeing evidence that other forms of diversity improve or at least do not harm investment outcomes, particularly outside the board. The reason that this question matters is that fund managers and the aforementioned endowments and public pension funds, are fiduciaries. That meant they are (at least in theory) not allowed to pursue otherwise meritorious-seeming social engineering if it impairs financial performance. We some evidence that it can at CalPERS, witness it having suffered two embarrassing and likely performance-impairing Chief Investment Officer departure in three years. CalPERS insisted twice on hiring unqualified CIOs over highly qualified white men, a demographic that dominates the high end of fund management. Longevity in tenure of a Chief Investment Officer is strongly correlated with better investment results, as the contrast between CalPERS and its higher-performring Sacramento giant pension fund sister, CalSTRS, attests.

As for “environment,” yours truly posits that it would be extremely difficult to construct an adequately diversified, at least environmentally neutral portfolio.

This post contends that ESG has often served to justify inaction on environmental and other collective priorities, as if investors could be relied upon to do policing. Aside from the fact that they don’t have the motivation to do so very well, Amar Bhide set forth an additional problem in his classic Harvard Business Review article, Efficient Markets, Deficient Governance. Investors in public stocks do not meaningfully supervise their investee companies. Unhappy shareholders will simply sell and move on rather than do the hard and not profitable work (in terms of return on their effort) of getting companies to shape up. The sole exception is activists who find particularly promising targets and accumulate enough shares to be a credible threat. The overwhelming majority of institutional investors have legal and/or commercial reasons not to operate that way.

However, this article unfortunately perpetuates the canard that companies have an obligation to maximize shareholder returns. That is a bogus idea first touted by Milton Friedman and that the very vocal Chicago School of Economics has nattered about long enough to have become widely accepted despite its lack of legal foundations.1

Equity is a residual claim. Boards are obligated to satisfy all other legal obligations, like legal and regulatory compliance, paying taxes, paying creditors, paying suppliers, paying workers, and having good controls (to make sure the preceding duties can be met) before they can and should think about shareholders. If you read big white shoe law firm guides for board directors, if there’s an overriding obligation, it’s “Don’t go bankrupt”.

By Siti Sarah Abdul Razak and Jomo Kwame Sundaram, a former economics professor, who was United Nations Assistant Secretary-General for Economic Development, and received the Wassily Leontief Prize for Advancing the Frontiers of Economic Thought. Originally published at Jomo’s website

Policy approaches relying solely on voluntary actions to address urgent needs are unlikely to succeed. Depending on optional compliance to address global warming will not fix things in time.

Regulation for Transformation

Tariq Fancy, former Chief Investment Officer for Sustainable Investing at BlackRock, had created a storm with his criticisms of ESG (environmental and social governance) ‘greenwashing’, remaining wary of voluntary corporate-led reforms.

Nevertheless, judicious and effective regulation based on ESG principles, combined with changing incentives and increased public awareness, can incentivize companies to do better.

Fancy believes changing rules for better regulation is essential for better outcomes. Limiting greenhouse gas (GHG) emissions is essential to ensure responsible governance aligned with the long-term public interest.

Investment managers have several responsibilities – including fiduciary duties, legal obligations, and financial incentives – requiring them to prioritize short-term profitability rather than sustainability.

Fancy believes imposing financial costs will provide stronger incentives for corporations to pursue greener alternatives. After all, voluntary measures are rarely enough to ensure sufficient adoption of sustainable practices.

Changing regulations to incorporate sustainability considerations should require portfolio managers to prioritize social and environmental concerns, and make choices supporting long-term sustainability goals.

Profits Not Aligned with Public Interest

Fiduciary duties oblige company managers to always act in the best interest of shareholder profits. This means ESG initiatives will only happen if they help, or at least do not hurt, profitability.

Fancy noted managers are not allowed, by law, to sacrifice potential profits from shareholder investments. They are legally obliged to never sacrifice shareholder interests, especially profitability, for anything else.

Social, cultural and media shifts in the West have undoubtedly influenced transnational business behaviour. The popularization of ESG discourses reflects these trends, but there is no strong evidence of their efficacy and positive impact.

Fleeting episodes of public attention cannot even ensure long-term protection of the public interest. With managers constrained by their fiduciary duties, relying on corporations to do the right thing is neither reliable nor sufficient.

Relying on corporate social or environmental responsibility may well become a distraction, delaying urgent and much-needed efforts. This failure underscores the need for government regulation and corporate compliance to achieve vital social and environmental goals.

Quick Fixes Delay Progress

Fancy found many people believe safeguarding investment portfolios from climate risks prevents global warming. But safeguarding finance from climate risks is not the same as mitigating climate change.

De-risking finance means protecting the financial value of an investment portfolio. This includes protecting against asset damage, or reducing the risk of lower investment returns, but certainly not climate change mitigation.

Mitigating climate change requires proactive measures to reduce GHG emissions. This includes measures to generate and use clean, especially renewable energy.

Financial protection is important for financial asset owners, but it cannot replace the efforts needed to fight climate change. Worse, believing such measures address the climate crisis serves to delay government interventions and other changes needed to do so.

Climate Inequity

Climate change exacerbates inequality, which in turn delays progress. The intergenerational distribution of the burden of climate risks disproportionately affects younger and future generations.

This deters proactive measures, as older generations are less inclined to spend more now for future generations who will suffer more from global warming. Instead, they may prefer measures to better adapt to its contemporary effects.

Aside from younger and future generations, the more vulnerable will also bear its worst effects. Thus, for example, small farmers in developing nations will have to cope with increased droughts, floods and crop failures.

Thus, further progress on climate change is delayed due to financial short-termist thinking, business interests, limited contemporary accountability for future consequences, as well as political and cost considerations.

Developing nations, with much smaller per capita carbon footprints, typically lack resources, leaving them more vulnerable. Meanwhile, developed countries, the major historical greenhouse gas emitters, have more resources to slow and adapt to climate change.

Can ESG Principles Help?

Will businesses maintain commitments to ESG ‘principles’ over the long term? They are legally obliged to maximize shareholder interests, especially profits, and also know public interest, attention, sentiment and priorities are always changing.

Business leaders may only commit to ESG principles in the long term if compelled to embrace them owing to the pecuniary costs of ignoring them. Obligations to other stakeholders – including investors, customers and employees – can also help sustain ESG commitments.

Establishing clear governance arrangements for ESG oversight, setting measurable and achievable goals, reporting regularly, and ensuring comprehensive organizational accountability should also help.

But ultimately, regulation should appropriately advance social and environmental responsibility, with such commitments sustained despite shifting public attention, fads and profit concerns.

Are Voluntary Efforts Enough?

The COVID-19 experience has also taught us to prioritize proactive, systemic and mandatory measures, rather than rely solely on voluntary efforts. While voluntary efforts can advance sustainability efforts, the pandemic experience suggests they will not be sufficient to achieve needed changes soon enough.

A systemic approach can induce businesses and individuals to do the needed. Policy interventions, especially regulation, are essential to drive systemic changes on a large scale, and to align businesses and individuals with ESG principles.

Clear communications, transparency and collaboration – among governments, businesses and civil society – are crucial for achieving long-term sustainability and progressive social change.

To control the pandemic, governments adopted ‘all of government’ and ‘whole of society’ approaches, imposing strict mandatory lockdowns, but also providing vaccinations to all, and support to the vulnerable.

Similar top-down approaches may be needed to effectively address social and sustainability challenges. This could involve implementing regulations, standards and incentives promoting, even requiring, sustainable practices.

_____

1 A very old Michigan Supreme Court decision has no precedential value outside Michigan.

Print Friendly, PDF & Email

3 comments

  1. TomDority

    Seeing that taxes are mandatory – might a few tweaks go a long way to dissuade in investments that are not sustainable or stock buy backs that are not related to actual production – or investements that only boom asset prices and increase the cost of living. Just saying – taxes have a lot of ability to direct the flow of investments in that profits are in the margins those taxes play a real role in profit margins

  2. David in Friday Harbor

    They lost me with the “act in the best interest of shareholder profits” canard. Governments should never extend the protections and benefits of incorporation solely to enable the extraction of rents by wealthy investors, directors, or managers.

    The authors correctly conclude that those same governments who confer on enterprises the benefits of incorporation have an obligation to impose “systemic and mandatory measures” to ensure that the corporations they have authorized conduct business in alignment with sustainable and progressive societal objectives — ESG.

    However, the Powell Memorandum led corporate managers and directors down the path of using corporate assets to capture the government that should be regulating their conduct for the benefit of the putatively sovereign democratic public interest and has stood the very notion of incorporation on its head — Inverted Totalitarianism.

    Investors have a duty to maximize the value of their shares, but enabling rent extraction by executives and directors of the corporation sure ain’t how to do that!

  3. Susan the other

    Daydreaming: Why can’t we peg all currencies to the health of the environment/ecology in the country(s) in question. (That is the countries where extraction and/or production tale place, as well as consumption.) For international corporations there would be several national currencies to maintain. Protection laws, etc. It would prevent race-to-the-bottom profiteering because that would be the fastest way to make money worthless. it would automatically impose capital controls, encourage long term investments, maybe stabilize all currency exchange, and promote good ecology and cleanup. And all those derivatives would be contingent on creating good ecology.

Comments are closed.