From the Great Divergence to South-South Divergence

Yves here. Now that the Global South, or as many prefer, the Global Majority countries have more economic heft and are collectively exerting more political power, the idea of lumping them all together is even more questionable than before. This post argues that the old “Great Divergence” model is past its sell-by date and other typologies would be more useful. It’s hardly a secret that some “developing” countries have moved smartly up in terms of per-capita incomes (even if they might still have hardscrabble hinterlands) while others are mired in poverty. But quite a few economists are apparently still treating them as too much of a muchness.

By Ewout Frankema, Professor of Economic and Environmental History, Wageningen University & Research. Originally published at VoxEU

The long era of the Great Divergence has come to an end with the rapid economic ascendance of Eastern Asia, and China in particular. But economic historians have yet to define an agenda to analyse the causes and consequences of the rapid, and more recent, economic divergence across the Global South. This column argues that there is an urgent need to focus on this South-South divergence.

The Great Divergence debate has been the field-defining conversation in economic history for the past 25 years. This debate revolves around the question why the Industrial Revolution originated in Western Europe, and more specifically in Britain, and not in China, India, or Japan. By unifying scholars around this comparative research agenda, the debate has done much to globalise the field of economic history and to stimulate the construction of world-spanning databases on historical GDP, real wages, skill premiums, government revenues, terms-of-trade, human capital, land use, and more. Such data collection and estimation efforts, in turn, have provoked heated discussion on the methodological and theoretical underpinnings of income and welfare measurements, and on the critical importance of reciprocity in comparative economic historical analyses. As is the case for all major academic debates, however, at some point of their life cycle decreasing marginal returns are inevitable. Once original questions fade as new adjacent windows of exploration open. Moreover, the long era of the Great Divergence – which is primarily, but not exclusively, understood as a Eurasian phenomenon – has come to an end with the rapid economic ascendance of Eastern Asia, and China in particular. As Ken Pomeranz already observed in his seminal book The Great Divergence (Pomeranz 2000), the last quarter of the 20th was characterised by impressive rates of convergence, not divergence. In light of both developments, the academic and the historical, in a recent paper (Frankema 2023) I ask: what are the new comparative horizons in global economic history?

Beyond the Great Divergence

I argue that there is an urgent need to focus on the rapid, and more recent, economic divergence across the Global South. I refer to this new divide as South-South divergence. As the Eurasian gap in economic, industrial, and technological capacity began to shrink, the South began to experience growing disparities in labour productivity and per capita income. This process of South-South divergence is illustrated in Figure 1, which shows the coefficient of variation of per capita GDP in the North and the South since 1950. In the South the income disparities widened, while in the North they narrowed, a trend that was only temporarily interrupted by the disintegration of former communist economies during the 1980s and 1990s. This phenomenon of South-South divergence warrants more attention than it has received thus far.

Figure 1 Coefficient of variation of per capita GDP in the Global North and Global South, 1950-2018

Source: GDP per capita from Maddison Project Database 2020.
Note: The coefficients of variation in GDP per capita are taken from a constant sample of 40 Northern and 105 Southern countries listed in Appendix 1. The Global South excludes the oil-rich Gulf Countries; the Global North excludes the former Soviet states that gained independence in the 1990s.

To be sure, the attention that has been devoted to the economic history of developing regions has greatly increased over the past two decades. New research networks, conferences and journals have been established. However, for the most part, these research communities have lacked an explicit trans-regional comparative agenda. They have made great progress on debating topics such as Latin American inequality, African colonial legacies, Middle Eastern culture and religious institutions, or comparative patterns of Asian industrialisation, but seldom do these communities venture out to discuss the nature and drivers of cross-regional divergence. Economic historians have yet to define an agenda to analyse the causes and consequences of divergence in the Global South.

Why Care About South-South Divergence?

Let me offer four reasons. First, whereas the Global South today already comprises more than 80% of the world population and generates close to 60% of world GDP, its demographic and economic weight is bound to increase further during the 21st century. By 2100 the North is projected to hold just 12% of the world population, while Asia and Africa together will harbor more than 80% of the world population. The share of world GDP that will accrue to the South is projected to rise from 57% in 2020 to 72% in 2050.

Table 1 Population and income shares per world region, 1820-2100

Source: 1820-1900 from Maddison Project Database 2020; 1950-2100 from UNDP, World Population Prospects, 2022 revision, medium variant.
Note: Europe includes all former Soviet republics and Central Asian states; Asia includes New Zealand and Australia.

Second, this reconfiguration of global economic gravity is having profound implications for global divisions of labour, capital flows, trade, food demands, investment, and migration patterns. In fact, one of the most important consequences of South-South divergence has already materialised: the problem of extreme poverty, which had long been a predominantly Asian phenomenon, has shifted decisively towards sub-Saharan Africa. While back in 1990 more than four out of five of the world’s extreme poor were living in Asia, in 2020 two out of three of the world’s extreme poor lived in Africa (ca. 65%).

Third, economic history students who have to be trained in recognising, studying, and interpreting the drivers of long-term divergence and convergence will have to be introduced to these global shifts in order to make sense of them. But where is the literature that we prescribe to teach the chapter on South-South divergence? After all, the Great Divergence did not just end with the era of the Great Convergence (Baldwin 2016), it also shifted the locus of global inequality, a shift that is reconfiguring the 21st century world economy with dazzling speed.

And finally, fourth, in a field that has long been dominated by Western-centred research agendas and North-South perspectives, more systematic engagement with South-South comparisons can lead to new data collection efforts and can help to develop reciprocal comparisons without taking Western economic development as the mirror image. In this regard, the South-South divergence agenda can take the call for reciprocal comparisons to a next level. Western imperialism may play an important role in understanding the roots of South-South divergence, but it does not have to serve as the ultimate benchmark to measure performance.

Is the South a Useful Category?

I admit that lumping the world together in two blocks may appear old-fashioned. The idea of juxtaposing the North versus the South goes back to 1980, when the Brandt Report published the famous map shown in Figure 2. How useful is ‘the South’ as an analytical category given its enormous historical diversity in populations, cultures, states, and institutions? I argue that taking the South as a world on its own is defendable, if one allows for hybrid cases (e.g. Japan, Turkey) and is willing to accept the notion of the ‘quadruple challenge’. The quadruple challenge refers to the idea that virtually all Southern states had (or have) to, simultaneously, grapple with the questions of:

  1. How to catch-up with technology leaders in the West while being at a considerable distance from the frontier.
  2. How to overcome the variegated legacies of externally imposed institutions (colonialism) or extended phases of limited state autonomy as a result of imperialist and neo-colonialist pressures.
  3. How to mediate the forces of accelerated globalisation, in particular the volatility of world commodity markets and rising capital flows in the context of their distance to global productivity frontiers.
  4. How to deal with increasing constraints on cross-border mobility of labour in the context of heightened environmental pressures (the Anthropocene) including climate change.

If these binding elements suffice as a binding core of similarities, then the diversity in local institutions, geographies and colonial trajectories can provide ample material for analysing how these threads intertwine and have led to strongly divergent post-colonial development paths.

Figure 2 The Brandt line

Source: Brandt et al. (1980, p. 31-32) and front cover.

Leading Questions

There are numerous big questions that can inspire a South-South divergence research agenda. My paper elaborates three of these. First, what explains the limited spread of the developmental state as it emerged in Eastern Asia, and how can other types of political-economic regimes be qualified? This question has been hitherto been mainly of interest to political scientists. Historians can contribute much to these debates by bringing in deeper time scales, diachronic comparative lenses, and more dynamic conceptions of colonial institutional development. Second, why is development clustered in space and time? Is it nature (geography, agrarian structures, deep-seated cultures) or should we focus on nurture: how regional processes of integration and disintegration have taken shape in Latin America, sub-Sahara Africa, the Middle East or Southeast Asia? Third, can the whole world be developed? To what extent do the newly industrialising economies of Asia jeopardise the opportunities of African economies to conquer new niches in world markets? How does the rising pressure and rising prices of scarce raw materials draw mining economies deeper into their paths of natural resource exploitation? These three questions are obviously not exhaustive, but they are all  relevant for economic policymaking in the Global South.

In sum, my paper offers a plea to integrate the global South in the historiography of global economic development on its own terms, and to rethink, how new comparative horizons can open up to move the agenda away from the old question how the West got rich or weird (Henrich 2020), and to the new question why modern capacities to enhance human welfare have so far spread so unevenly across the globe.

See original post for references

Print Friendly, PDF & Email

13 comments

  1. Patrick Morrison

    I have a question about Table 1 in the article. The ‘Global North’ total matches the sum of the Europe and Americas rows for 1850, but varies to some degree in every other case. Is there an unseen variable, e.g. distinguishing between North and South America for the total, is my assumption about their being a relationship wrong, or is there a mistake in the data entry?

    1. vidimi

      probably the antipodean countries. They didn’t have an economy yet in 1850.

      My observation about that chart is that the coeffivient of variation has actually not increased in the global south in 30 years and has actually been decreasing over the last 10 while India has been catching up. The observation therefore seems a bit late.

  2. Kilgore Trout

    The Brandt line map of the nations of the global majority should add a dashed or solid line to include the Russian Federation, since the Ukraine war has secured Russia’s exclusion from Europe and the collective West– the now dimming Neo-constellation of the global minority.

    1. ChrisRUEcon

      Ha! Was thinking the same thing myself. Such a line dwarfs the loop that excludes Australia and New Zealand from the global south. I’m still wondering which “European” country will be the first to bolt southward.

    2. Joe Well

      I think the USSR was pretty diverged from the Collective West in 1980 when the line was first drawn.

      1. Polar Socialist

        Yes, but the countries above the line were the ones either reaping the benefits of Bretton Woods or at least not being harmed (much) by it. The countries below the line are the ones being, well, exploited by the international system.

        Maybe with the exception of Cuba, Angola and Vietnam that were using USSR resources trough Comecon and direct subsidies. And of course China managing to make it’s own way out of poverty trough being forced to operate outside of the “benevolence” of IMF for decades.

  3. Paris

    Kazakhstan in the global north? Anyway, I think that whole Global South definition spurious to say the least. More or less like the Brics definition. Those countries are so different in everything that putting them together has to be a thing from eurocentric/us-centric northerners who know nothing about the world.

    1. Samuel

      Yeah, I too cannot see how generalising half the globe into a set of arbitrarily defined standards by the author — the “quadruple challenge” — which, even if taken as a perspective of some local politicians and organisations in the countries of the “Global South,” can be in any way useful analytically. The sheer idea of playing catch-up with the “West” smells of eurocentrism: the politicians of the “Global South” certainly don’t (only) take as an example some imagined “Western” model of development.

      Perhaps a more interesting study would be to start with the hypothesis or research question on whether and how certain politicians in some “Global South” countries, educated in “Western” university institutions helped recreate colonial/neo-colonial structures, while propagandising the neo-liberal story of playing “catch-up” with the West.

      Besides adopting standards of measurements is itself colonialism of the mind. What’s more important: catching up with GDP or a well-fed, healthy populace?

    2. Steven A

      The Brandt Line was drawn in 1980 and meant to include the entire former USSR, including Kazakhstan and all the ‘Stans. i encountered this line as a grad student in an introductory international relations course and the map depicted the USSR in the North as a single entity.

      Your assertion that the Brandt line shows a Euro/US-centric perspective may have some merit. When I first viewed this map in my student days I wondered if Albania should have been included in the North. Note that the line makes a hairpin turn to include Israel. Also, if the line were redrawn today it would likely have to bend to include South Korea and Singapore in the North.

  4. Hickory

    Interesting study, though I agree with other commenters it doesn’t illuminate alliances well. Also Kazahkstan in the north seems odd. Did they industrialize much in soviet times?

    Amazing to think what would have happened if the US allowed Russia into nato and didn’t allow china into the wto, and only made one enemy instead of two. That brandt line might actually represent an alliance in that case.

  5. Willow

    An economic interpretation of the Global North/Global South will always ill fit when distinction is political – Colonialist North, Non-Colonialist (predominantly colonized) South. Which is why Russia is an outlier above and Israel below the Brandt line. As such impact is less about economics and more about challenging the colonialist ‘rules based order’. There will be economic consequences but political impact on global institutions will be far greater. This is where the real danger for the West is.

  6. eg

    “why modern capacities to enhance human welfare have so far spread so unevenly across the globe.”

    Unequal terms of trade imposed by the colonial powers seem to me to be a good place to start.

Comments are closed.