How Workers and Firms Meet in the Labour Market and Why It Matters

By Carlos Carrillo-Tudela, Professor at University Of Essex, Leo Kaas, Professor of Economics at Goethe University Frankfurt, and Benjamin Lochner, Senior Researcher at Institute for Employment Research (IAB). Originally published at VoxEU.

Most firms match with workers through job postings, networks of personal contacts, or the public employment agency. This column investigates the effects of search channels on labour market outcomes in Germany. Low-wage firms and low-wage workers are more likely to match via networks or the public agency, while high-wage firms and high-wage workers succeed more often via job postings. Because search channels connect workers and firms at different rungs of the wage distribution, matching technologies matter not only for individual job search outcomes, but also for aggregate employment, productivity, and wage inequality.

Matching frictions in the labour market are central for understanding the roots of high unemployment and labour shortages in modern economies. Next to the adverse effects on aggregate economic activity, matching frictions impede efficient job-worker allocations with detrimental consequences for firm productivity and workers’ wage growth (e.g. Guvenen et al. 2020, Kugler et al. 2021, Tåg et al. 2022).

In order to deal with costly and time-intensive job search and recruiting activities, workers and firms apply various strategies. In particular, both sides of the labour market make use of different search channels to reduce search costs and facilitate better match quality. While job postings allow firms to reach many suitable applicants, networks of personal contacts help workers and firms gain information about each other prior to job interviews (e.g. Brown et al. 2016, Cappellari and Tatsiramos 2015, Dustmann et al. 2016). Further, in many European countries, public employment agencies help job seekers through bespoke job search assistance (Lalive et al. 2018, Belot et al. 2019, Merkl and Sauerbier 2023).

While previous research has studied the effects of specific search channels on workers’ labour market outcomes, little is known about the overall use of search channels by workers and firms and the resulting match outcomes. Understanding the extent to which search channels have differential effects on the matching process is key for the analysis of wage inequality, aggregate productivity, and other labour market outcomes.

In a recent paper (Carrillo-Tudela et al. 2023), we make use of unique linked data to investigate the degree to which search channels affect the matching process between heterogeneous firms and heterogeneous workers. These data – provided by Germany’s Institute for Employment Research (IAB) – combine a worker survey about job search behaviour, a firm survey about recruitment behaviour, and an administrative firm-worker dataset containing the full employment and earnings biographies of private-sector employees in the German labour market. The two survey datasets not only provide information about firms’ and workers’ use of search channels, but also about the search channel that led to a hire (of a firm) or to a new job (of a searching worker). These data reveal that job postings and personal networks are the two dominant search channels in the German labour market, accounting together for almost 70% of all hires (followed by the public employment agency, which accounts for another 13% of hires).

The administrative matched worker-firm dataset can be used to estimate wage ranks of firms and workers based on AKM fixed effects (so-named for the authors of Abowd et al. 1999; see also Card et al. 2013). Broadly speaking, a firm with a high AKM fixed effect pays higher wages relative to a firm with a lower AKM fixed effect irrespective of the workforce quality, possibly because the former firm is more productive. Likewise, a worker with a high AKM fixed effect tends to earn a higher wage at any firm relative to another worker with a lower AKM fixed effect, possibly because the former worker has better skills.

Linking these AKM fixed effects to the two survey datasets allows us to examine how firms and workers of different wage ranks match in the labour market. Figure 1 shows the relationships between the firms’ AKM fixed effects and the probability of hiring through either job postings, networks, or the public employment agency. As can be seen, high-wage firms hire more frequently via job postings compared to low-wage firms, while they succeed less often through networks or through the public employment agency where low-wage firms are more likely to hire. Importantly, these relationships are conditional on the educational requirement of the job and on firm size, firm age, or industry, which all matter independently for recruitment strategies. These results show that firms of different wage ranks match differentially through the three search channels, regardless of other important firm or job characteristics.

Figure 1 Hiring probability through job postings, networks, and public employment agency by firms’ wage ranks

Source: Carrillo-Tudela et al. (2023)

Figure 2 illustrates the corresponding relationships between the workers’ AKM fixed effect and the probability of finding a job through job postings, networks, or the public employment agency. The results are strikingly similar to those on the firm side: high-wage workers are more likely to find a job via postings compared to low-wage workers, while low-wage workers are more likely to find a job via networks or the public employment agency compared to high-wage workers. These relationships are conditional on various worker characteristics such as age, gender, and previous employment status, as well as the occupation of the job. Hence, the relationships between the worker’s wage rank and the successful search channel are not driven by composition effects along these dimensions.

Figure 2 Probability of finding a job through job postings, networks, and public employment agency by workers’ wage ranks

Source: Carrillo-Tudela et al. (2023)

Taken together, our results indicate that high-wage firms and high-wage workers match more frequently via job postings, while low-wage firms and low-wage workers match relatively more via networks or the public employment agency. To investigate the role of search channels for labour market sorting, we go a step further. Separately for each of the three successful search channels – and again conditional on the firm and job controls applied previously – we consider the relationship between the hired worker’s wage rank and the hiring firm’s wage rank. The results, shown in Figure 3, lead to two conclusions. First, firms generally succeed in employing higher-ranked workers via job postings compared to personal networks and especially in comparison to the public employment agency, which generates matches with lower-ranked workers. Second, all channels facilitate positive sorting in that high-wage workers are more likely to match with high-wage workers compared to low-wage firms, where the positive sorting relationship is strongest for the job-postings channel.

Figure 3 Relationship between worker and firm wage ranks separately for the hiring channel job postings, networks, and public employment agency

Source: Carrillo-Tudela et al. (2023)

It is well understood that workers’ job mobility plays a key role for individual wage dynamics, wage inequality, and for the wage and hiring policies of heterogeneous firms (e.g. Burdett and Mortensen 1998, Postel-Vinay and Robin 2002). Our data give unique insights into the role of search channels for job-to-job turnover and wage-ladder dynamics. On the firm side, we find that job postings provide the highest probability of poaching a worker from another firm, especially for firms higher up the wage distribution. We also show that workers achieve the largest positive steps on the wage ladder when they find a job via job postings: a job-to-job transition through job postings is associated with an increase of the employer’s average wage level that is 2–3 percentage points larger compared to a job-to-job transition through the other search channels.

Given these empirical relationships, we build and estimate a structural equilibrium model with two-sided heterogeneity in order to analyse the role of search channels for productivity, wages, and employment. One important purpose of the model is to evaluate the impact of the public employment agency for aggregate and distributional labour market outcomes. As in many other countries, Germany’s public employment agency supports job seekers individually through bespoke advice from placement officers. We consider a counterfactual scenario in which this placement service is abolished, while firms and workers are allowed to redirect their search effort to the other search channels. We find that the removal of the public placement service has large macroeconomic effects: aggregate employment and output decline by 1.4% and 0.8%, respectively, where the largest employment losses are realised for workers at the bottom of the productivity distribution. Moreover, when workers at the bottom and middle of the productivity distribution find jobs, they end up employed in firms with lower average productivity. As a result, wage inequality widens such that the 90–50 and 50–10 percentile ratios go up by 3.3% and 1.2%, respectively.

Overall, our results highlight that matching technologies matter decisively for labour market outcomes: different search channels bring together workers and firms at different rungs of the wage distribution. Hence, they matter not only for individual job search outcomes, but also for aggregate employment, productivity, and wage inequality.

References available at the original.

Print Friendly, PDF & Email

This entry was posted in Economic fundamentals, Guest Post, Income disparity, Market inefficiencies, The destruction of the middle class on by .

About Lambert Strether

Readers, I have had a correspondent characterize my views as realistic cynical. Let me briefly explain them. I believe in universal programs that provide concrete material benefits, especially to the working class. Medicare for All is the prime example, but tuition-free college and a Post Office Bank also fall under this heading. So do a Jobs Guarantee and a Debt Jubilee. Clearly, neither liberal Democrats nor conservative Republicans can deliver on such programs, because the two are different flavors of neoliberalism (“Because markets”). I don’t much care about the “ism” that delivers the benefits, although whichever one does have to put common humanity first, as opposed to markets. Could be a second FDR saving capitalism, democratic socialism leashing and collaring it, or communism razing it. I don’t much care, as long as the benefits are delivered. To me, the key issue — and this is why Medicare for All is always first with me — is the tens of thousands of excess “deaths from despair,” as described by the Case-Deaton study, and other recent studies. That enormous body count makes Medicare for All, at the very least, a moral and strategic imperative. And that level of suffering and organic damage makes the concerns of identity politics — even the worthy fight to help the refugees Bush, Obama, and Clinton’s wars created — bright shiny objects by comparison. Hence my frustration with the news flow — currently in my view the swirling intersection of two, separate Shock Doctrine campaigns, one by the Administration, and the other by out-of-power liberals and their allies in the State and in the press — a news flow that constantly forces me to focus on matters that I regard as of secondary importance to the excess deaths. What kind of political economy is it that halts or even reverses the increases in life expectancy that civilized societies have achieved? I am also very hopeful that the continuing destruction of both party establishments will open the space for voices supporting programs similar to those I have listed; let’s call such voices “the left.” Volatility creates opportunity, especially if the Democrat establishment, which puts markets first and opposes all such programs, isn’t allowed to get back into the saddle. Eyes on the prize! I love the tactical level, and secretly love even the horse race, since I’ve been blogging about it daily for fourteen years, but everything I write has this perspective at the back of it.

2 comments

  1. Jeremy Grimm

    “Overall, our results highlight that matching technologies matter decisively for labor market outcomes: different search channels bring together workers and firms at different rungs of the wage distribution. Hence, they matter not only for individual job search outcomes, but also for aggregate employment, productivity, and wage inequality.”

    PROBLEM SOLVED!!!!! The World needs new APPS!!!!!
    Automated job searching seems like a great application for an AI program designed to help workers find employment and employers find workers. Consider the time savings and efficiencies that might be accomplished by an AI running multiple web crawlers and firing emails into networks, perhaps initiating calls into ‘friend’ contacts using voice simulations of the job seeker. AI could bring an era of no-fuss-no-muss unemployment, greatly easing the aggravations and fears of the unemployed. Perhaps Apple might come out with an app … a phone app for iPhone. The complexities of employment “Markets” need no long trouble the unemployed.\s

  2. Darthbobber

    This is the sort of combined “solution seeking” and apologetics that Meszaros mocked so caustically in the nineties.

    Even if the matching game were being played perfectly, it could obviously not compensate for the continuing shedding of labor power across the board in the developed economies. And nor is it intended to.

    Such things “matter decisively for labor market outcomes” only if one is assuming the indefinite continuation of capitalism and equating the best it can do with the best that can e done. And even then, “matter decisively” is a huge stretch as the effect can only be marginal.

    Better matching, better training, grater flexibility, reduction of friction have been being peddled as panaceas for my entire adult life, without ever producing ay positive results beyond propaganda value.

Comments are closed.