Yves here. Despite many pretenses, very little in finance is new, much the less innovative. Paul Volcker still looks correct in calling the ATM the only bank invention in his lifetime. In Econned, we mentioned that virtually all of the features of modern finance were found in Ur in 1788 BC, such as venture capital, loan syndications and sales, secured lending, and derivatives. But bank havens, also known as offshore, were not on that particular list. Hudson fills in that gap by describing the key elements of these hidden money caches and naming ancient analogues
By Michael Hudson, an American economist, a professor of economics at the University of Missouri–Kansas City, and a researcher at the Levy Economics Institute at Bard College. He is a former Wall Street analyst, political consultant, commentator, and journalist. You can read more of Hudson’s economic history on the Observatory. Produced by Human Bridges
A discussion of the origins of urbanization may provide some insight into the character of modern social problems by highlighting the long historical dynamic at work. It may not be out of place here to point out that anti‑states are well known in the modern world, above all in what the U.S. Federal Reserve Board classifies as eleven offshore banking centers. Five such enclaves are in the Caribbean: Panama, the Netherlands Antilles (Curacao), Bermuda, the Bahamas, and the British West Indies (Cayman Islands). Three enclaves—Hong Kong, Macao, and Singapore—were founded to conduct the China trade. The remaining three are Liberia, Lebanon, and Bahrain at the mouth of the Persian Gulf—the island which Bronze Age Sumerians called Dilmun when they used it to trade with the Indus valley and the Iranian shore.
Nothing would seem more modern than these offshore banking and tax-avoidance centers. They are the brainchildren of lawyers and accountants in the 1960s seeking to weave loopholes into the social fabric—to provide curtains of secrecy (“privacy”) to avoid or evade taxes, and to serve as havens for ill‑gotten earnings as well as to facilitate legitimate commerce.
Whereas modern nation‑states enact laws and impose taxes, these enclaves help individuals evade such regulations. And whereas nation‑states have armies, these centers are the furthest thing from being military powers. They are antibodies to nationhood, yet more may be learned about Ice Age, Neolithic, and even Bronze Age gathering and meeting sites by looking at these modern enclaves than by examining classical city‑states such as Athens and Rome.
Timeless Features of Entrepots
- They Lack Political Autonomy
Instead of being politically independent, the modern offshore banking centers and free trade zones are small former colonies, e.g., the Caribbean islands as well as the Chinese entrepots. The Grand Cayman Island was a Jamaican dependency until 1959, when it chose to revert to its former status as a British crown colony so as to benefit from what remained of imperial commercial preferences. Liberia and Panama are U.S. dependencies lacking even their own currency system (both use the U.S. dollar). Hong Kong did not gain title to its own land until Britain’s leases expired in 1997. Panama did not gain control of its canal until 1999.
In sum, whereas political theorists define the first characteristic of modern states (and implicitly their capital cities) as being their ability to enact and enforce laws, offshore banking centers are of no political significance. In the sense of being sanctuaries from national taxes and law authorities, such enclaves are in some ways akin to the biblical cities of refuge. If they are not sanctuaries for lawbreakers in person, they at least provide havens for their bank accounts and corporate shells.
- They Occupy Convenient Points of Commercial Interface Between Regions
Typically, entrepots are on islands or key transport navels such as the Panamanian isthmus. They are separated as free ports politically, if not physically, from their surrounding political entities. They often are centers of travel and tourism (“business meetings”) and for gambling. In antiquity they typically were centers for sacred festivals or games such as were held at Delphi, Nemia, the Corinthian Isthmus, or Olympia (whence our modern Olympic games originated in a sacred context).
- They Enjoy Sacred (or Legal) Protection Against Attack
Although Delphi and Olympus were landlocked (as was Çatal Hüyük), they were centrally located for their local regions. They served as religious and cultural centers, whose festivals and games could be conveniently attended by the Hellenic population at large. Even visitors who were citizens of mutually belligerent city‑states enjoyed sanctuary. Of course, today’s enclaves no longer claim sacred status, except for the Vatican and its Institute for Religious Works promoting money-laundering functions1. Their commercial focus has become divorced from the religious setting associated with international commerce down through medieval Europe with its great fairs. And indeed, their attraction is especially to wealthy individuals avoiding the tax laws and criminal codes of their own homeland.
- They Are Militarily Safe
Although today’s enclaves rarely have armies of their own, they are militarily safe. Thanks to their unique apolitical status, and indeed to their ultimate dependence on larger powers, their neighbors have little motive to attack them and every reason to use them as business channels and even for government transactions such as arms dealing, money laundering, and related activities not deemed proper behavior at home. The resulting commerce thrives free of regulations and taxes, conducted in militarily safe environments without the cost of having to support standing armies, and hence less need to levy taxes for this purpose, or to monetize national war debts.
- They Are Politically Neutral Sites
To create such enclaves has been an objective of mercantile capital through the ages. It patronizes the world’s politically weakest areas as long as they do not do what real governments do: regulate their economies. The search for “neutral territory” expressed itself already in the chalcolithic epoch, many millennia before private enterprise developed as we know it. The result of this impetus is that neolithic towns such as Çatal Hüyük, Mesopotamian temple cities such as Nippur, island entrepots such as Dilmun, the Egyptian Delta area, Ischia/Pithekoussai, and the biblical cities of refuge share the following important common denominator with today’s offshore banking centers: Instead of being centers of local governing, legal, and military power, they were politically neutral sites established outside the jurisdictions of local governments.
- They Create Forums for Rituals of Social Cohesion
Whether the status of these urban sites was that of sanctified commercial entrepots or amphictyonic centers, they provided a forum for rituals of social cohesion to bolster their commerce. These rituals included the exchange of goods and women (intermarriage)—commerce and intercourse in their archaic sexual meaning as well as in the more modern sense of commodity exchange.
I have cited above the archaic practice of conducting trade via island entrepots. The sacred island of Dilmun/Bahrain in the Persian Gulf represents history’s longest lasting example of such an enclave. It served as an entrepôt linking Sumer and Babylonia (whose records refer prominently to the “merchants of Dilmun”) to the Indus civilization and the intervening Iranian shore. Its status as a sacred as well as commercial center may have been promoted by the fact that its waters were a source of pearls, prized as sacred symbols of the moon (being round, pale, and associated with deep water). It also seems to have served as a high‑status burial ground for prosperous individuals, or at least for parts of their bodies. Lamberg‑Karlovsky2 reports that there are more fingers and other limbs than full skeletons, as the Sumerians partook piecemeal in the island’s sanctity (although some commentators believe that this may be simply the result of grave robberies through the centuries3). In any event, these social and commercial virtues helped make Dilmun one of the most expensive pieces of Bronze Age real estate, not unlike modern Bahrain.
- They Facilitate Commercial Development
The sacred status of such entrepots facilitated commercial development in ways that did not abuse Bronze Age sensibilities, much like the sacred status of temples did when they became the major economic and textile production centers. While creating the economic conditions and organization of large‑scale enterprise within traditional social values and order, Bronze Age institutions provided leeway so as not to stifle commercial development with overcentralized control. This may be part of the reason why trade was conducted outside the city gates. The philosophy was to create “mixed economies” in which institutional and private sectors each had their proper role.
_____
1. David A. Yallop, In God’s Name: An Investigation into the Murder of Pope John Paul I, 1984, pp. 92-94.↩
2. C.C. Lamberg-Karlovsky “Dilmun: Gateway to Immortality,” Journal of Near Eastern Studies, Jan 1982, 41(1), pp. 45-50.↩
3. P.R.S. Moorey, “Where did they bury the Kings of the IIIrd Dynasty of Ur?” Iraq, 46, 1984, pp. 1‑18.↩
How did these ancient intrepols function as tax havens? Does Hudson make any recommendations for how such tax havens might be controlled or eliminated? It appears powerful economic forces mandate their existence.
My “Finance Capitalism and its Discontents: Interviews and Speeches, 2003-2012 (ISLET, 2012). has my introduction to Tom Naylor’s book that was the first on these banking centers.
I produce State Dept. documents showing that the US sponsored them to help finance the Vietnam War by making the US the “newSwitzerland” to attract criminal capital to create a dollar inflow.
And what to do about it. Freeze the accounts and demand proof of the source of this money.
So basically the same as in 2008, when supposedly the banks were told to ignore the law and accept deposits from known drug cartels so they could stay solvent?
Why are your books not on Audible? I repeatedly search but never find many on Audible. Are they available on any other audio book platforms maybe? And may I say I am a great fan of yours and any time I get depressed with America I think of you and people like Scott Ritter and Larry Johnson and so many other brave truth tellers who are still risking everything to inform the public.
Perhaps when the ongoing rot/collapse of US/EU/UK Capitalism reveals itself clearly, those havens will disappear.
Andorra, Lichtenstein, Switzerland, Monaco, Gibraltar, and a few others. Special freeports and tax regimes in all sorts of countries.
Corruption spreads …
Interesting.
The Institute for Religious Works has become less swampy. It is one of the reforms done by Pope Francis. No wonder the barnacles in the hierarchy can’t stand him:
https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Institute_for_the_Works_of_Religion#2023
They didn’t have annual reports till about 2013. Hmmm. On the other hand, being audited by KPMG doesn’t say much about one’s accounting practices. Ironically, the indictments likely helped clean things up.
I’d argue that Venice served the functions mentioned in the article for much of its history. For many years, Venice kept to the lagoon and the islands, rather than trying to manage a mainland empire, and the aristocracy kept the doge and the Church under control. The official cathedral of Venice for centuries was San Pietro, well beyond the Arsenale, the great state-sponsored industrial center of Venice, and on an island that is about the last one before the lagoon. Yet Venice was a center for banking, for festivals (carnival), for trade and crafts, for courtesans and their businesses, and for publishing.
Thanks for the mentions and reminders that Delphi, with its treasuries maintained by various poleis, as well as artwork, was an emporium, as was Olympia, for similar reasons.
I think many ancient societies had the concept of a sort of geographic or conceptual ‘safe space’ where normal laws and customs were suspended in order to allow what was perceived to be good business could thrive. Some Celtic societies(and probably the Bronze age societies who preceded them) seem to have had variations on what have been translated as ‘hostels’ – large compounds owned by the wealthy where enmities could be put to one side and travellers could be assured of a bed and food without questions asked. Presumably, these were very useful for adventurous traders. Arguably, this is what the great neolithic stone circles such as Stonehenge of western Europe represent – not just religious symbols, but essentially neutral areas where people could get together once a year and trade without hindrance under the guise of serving the gods (funny how religion invariably ends up facilitating wealth).
Some medieval towns had what were sometimes known as ‘liberties’ – essentially free trade zones where you were free of feudal rules and free of the towns taxes – they were popular for wandering craftspeople or tradespeople (and presumably moneylenders) who wanted to run a business without any interference. The downside was that if you didn’t pay taxes, then when bandits arrived, you couldn’t hide behind the city walls. It was a constant of European medieval towns that there would be an uncomfortable balance between the outside feudal lord/king, the establishment guilds, and various incomer groups (often brought in deliberately to promote industry), the latter of whom usually had the choice of becoming part of the establishment (i.e. absorbed by guilds), or maintaining some degree of independence, leaving them vulnerable to the covetous with more weapons. Occasionally, entire new towns would form from either disgruntled outsiders deciding to pack up and leave (this led to the eastern expansion of German towns), or being uprooted and resettled for the benefit of feudal leaders (French bastides).
Certainly, Dark Ages and Medieval Europe had many such ‘neutral’ zones, whether monasteries, individual towns, or areas outside towns, where feudal rules and taxes didn’t apply. Its been argued that this ‘flexibility’ gave European cultures a distinct advantage over others more rigid hierarchical societies when it came to taking advantage of technological changes.
Many native American nations used Kentucky in that manner, as neutral territory. They were apalled when the white people came over and started building cabins and putting up fences in that neutral area. People could come, visit and hunt as Kentucky was quite rich in resources – to be shared by all – until whitey showed up of course.
This seems related to our practice of making small cities the capitals of major states. I remember being surprised that Juneau could not be reached by road, and probably never would be. That said something me.
Islands have the advantage that one can know exactly who everyone is, and simply banish undesirables by giving them a one-way ferry ticket. Most of the islands served by the Maine ferry service have no police in residence.
“Of course, today’s enclaves no longer claim sacred status, except for the Vatican and its Institute for Religious Works promoting money-laundering functions1.”
Michael Hudson cites David Yallop’s book. We read that years ago. As Americans were were astonished by what Yallop was rightly pointing out,
It wasn’t until we met a well educated Italian who explained that the rot in Rome started far back in time: mid to later medieval ages. It’s the cardinals, who today, hold all the power while the current Pope is a mere figurehead.
Not to demean Catholics: most all Western Churches are riffed by thieves within/outside of its temples.Need we mention: the US Evangelical Church?