US Firms Have Little Financial Incentive to Comply with the Minimum Wage

Yves here. This is pathetic. America has a super low Federal minimum wage, of $7.25 an hour. It was increased to that level in 2009. That is equivalent to roughly $10.60 an hour, using a CPI calculator, which understates the increases in the cost of living to low-income workers, based on food price increases alone.

But on top of that, it turns out cheating pays. Minimum wage enforcement is so weak and fines are so low that non-compliance is a good economic bet.

By Anna Stansbury, Assistant Professor in Work and Organization Studies Massachusetts Institute of Technology (MIT). Originally published at VoxEU

A minimum wage is only effective to the degree it is actually paid – and research suggests that minimum wage non-compliance is very common. This column uses data on all violations of the Fair Labor Standards Act in the US documented since 2005 to ask what incentives US firms have to comply with the federal minimum wage. While the law allows for large penalties, average penalty levels are far too low to give most firms an incentive to comply. As the federal minimum wage is increased, higher penalties and greater enforcement will be needed to ensure compliance.

The US federal minimum wage is the baseline labour market protection for low-wage workers. Debates rage over how high it should be, in policy and in academia (e.g. Roth et al 2022, Cazes and Garnero 2023). 1 But a minimum wage is only effective to the degree it is actually paid – and research suggests that minimum wage non-compliance is very common. Random Department of Labor inspections of fast food outlets over 2001-2005, for example, found 40% in violation of Fair Labor Standards Act (FLSA) minimum wage or overtime provisions, and random garment industry inspections in 2015-2016 found FLSA violations in 85% of workplaces (Weil 2014, 2018). 2

In a new paper (Stansbury 2024), I compile case-level data on all FLSA violations identified by the Department of Labor since 2005 – combining publicly available data obtained in a Freedom of Information request. I use these data to ask: What incentive do US firms have to comply with the federal minimum wage? This question is important to understand the efficacy of existing minimum wage legislation, as well as to interpret other minimum wage research, including estimates of disemployment effects.

How to quantify a firm’s incentive to comply with the minimum wage? A long tradition in economics applies a cost-benefit framework to compliance decisions, suggesting that a profit-maximising company complies with the law if the extra profits made by breaking the law are less than the expected costs (Becker 1968). Taking this cost-benefit approach, I use data on penalties levied on violators to infer the penalties firms can expect to face under different scenarios – and thus, to estimate the degree to which firms have an incentive to comply with the minimum wage, under different assumptions about the probability of detection.

While the law allows for large penalties, few firms face penalties over and above paying the wages that they owed

The FLSA requires that all firms who underpay the minimum wage pay the back wages owed. They can also be required to pay an equal amount in liquidated damages. Willful or repeat violators can be charged a civil monetary penalty. In certain cases, the ‘hot goods provision’ can be used to embargo goods made in violation of the FLSA. And the most serious violators can be referred for criminal prosecution.

Yet, my analysis of the Department of Labor data shows that most firms face minimal costs for underpaying the minimum wage, over and above paying workers the wages originally owed.

Liquidated damages can in theory be levied on a large share of minimum wage violations. They were, however, almost never levied in DOL cases prior to 2012. This policy has changed in more recent years (Weil 2018). By 2022/2023, more than 30% of cases concluded had liquidated damages assessed. The remaining two thirds did not.

Willful and/or repeat violators may be required to pay a civil monetary penalty. But the vast majority of violations are not eligible for these penalties: 91% of violations detected by the DOL are first-time violations and of these, only 2% are deemed willful. That is, over 90% of violations are not eligible for any civil monetary penalty at all (at least under current legal interpretations of the definition of ‘willful’). Even among the repeat and/or willful violations eligible for a penalty, nearly half are charged no penalty. And even in the cases where civil monetary penalties are assessed, the amounts are small: the median repeat, non-willful violator in 2005-2023 was required to pay a penalty worth only 2 cents per dollar of back wages owed, and the median first-time willful violator was required to pay a penalty worth 15 cents per dollar of back wages owed. (Table 1). All this, taken together, means that only 6.5% of DOL-identified FLSA violations had any civil monetary penalty at all levied, and only 1.4% of cases received a penalty worth more than $1 per dollar of wages.

The ‘hot goods provision’ is almost entirely used in the garment industry (Weil 2018); among violations in other industries, the provision was used in only 0.15% of cases over 2005-2023.

Finally, criminal prosecutions are vanishingly rare: only 38 criminal convictions have occurred for violations of FLSA minimum wage or overtime provisions (sections 206, 207, 211C, 215, 216) over 1994-2020, according to data from the Bureau of Justice Statistics and Federal Criminal Case Processing Statistics. While the FLSA allows for fines of up to $10,000 and prison sentences of up to 6 months in criminal convictions, in practice fines were levied in only four cases, and none led to any prison time. Thus, among willful violations detected by the DOL, there was less than a 0.7% chance of a criminal conviction and a 0.08% chance of a criminal conviction with a fine.

Table 1 Liquidated damages and civil monetary penalty assessments in concluded Department of Labor FLSA investigations where back wages were owed, 2005-23, by violation type

Source: Department of Labor WHISARD database, all concluded WHD actions FY 2005 to July 2023
Note: “LD” = liquidated damages. “CMP” = civil monetary penalty.

Department of Labor investigations are not the only channel by which FLSA minimum wage violators can be identified: they can also be taken to court by employees in an individual or collective action. In this case, the employees will receive back wages plus an equal amount in liquidated damages. A major cost to violating firms is attorney fees: both their own, and the fees of the employee(s) if the employer loses the case. No civil monetary penalties can be levied in FLSA court cases.

Average penalty levels are far too low to give most firms an incentive to comply

With the data above, I infer the minimum probability of detection firms must expect, to have an incentive to comply. This is simply the reciprocal of the expected penalty per dollar of wages owed (Chang and Ehrlich 1985). I consider seven possible scenarios firms might face. In Figure 1, I illustrate for each scenario (1) the expected cost the firm will face if their violation is detected, as a share of back wages owed, and (2) the minimum probability of detection that the firm must expect to have an incentive to comply.

For a DOL investigation, the most likely scenarios are the ‘Average violator’ scenarios. As the figure shows, the average first-time violator faces total costs of $1.205 per dollar of back wages owed, meaning that they would need to expect an 83% chance of detection to incentivise compliance. If the violator knows that their violation would be deemed willful if detected, the average penalty rises to $2.09 per dollar of back wages owed – but this still means that the firm would need to expect a 48% chance of detection to incentivise compliance. 3

Costs are higher in court, since we estimate that any attorney fee awards plus the employer’s own legal costs combined would amount to around twice the total value of back wages owed (although this can vary widely). In court, we expect an average violator to face a cost of $4 per dollar of back wages owed, meaning they would need to expect a 25% chance of a successful court case against them to have an incentive to comply.

Figure 1 Incentives to comply with the FLSA under different scenarios

Source: Authors’ calculations, based on DOL enforcement data and data from FLSA cases (obtained using Westlaw).

Actual probabilities of detection are likely substantially lower than this. Using data on inspections and violations in fast food from Weil (2014b), I estimate that the average violating establishment has a 1.4% chance of being detected through a targeted DOL inspection in a given year – or a 4.2% chance over three years, the maximum length for which back wages can be claimed. That is, even under relatively effective targeting, detection probabilities would need to increase by more than an order of magnitude to reach the range of 48%-83% which my estimates suggest is required to incentivise compliance at current penalty levels. And while violations are frequently detected through worker complaints or court actions, these cannot be relied on to surface underpayment, particularly from the most vulnerable workers: workers may fear retaliation or job loss, or may not know their employer’s pay practices are illegal (e.g. Weil and Pyles 2006, Bobo 2011).

Higher penalties and greater enforcement are needed to ensure minimum wage compliance

For many firms in the US, then, the existing penalty and enforcement system for the FLSA does not create sufficient incentive to comply. Compliance incentives can be improved by increasing penalties and/or the probability of detection. The two are inversely related: to create an effective deterrent the expected penalty must increase exponentially as the probability of detection declines. My estimates suggest increases on both margins are needed.

When considering appropriate penalties, it is illustrative to note that the penalties firms face for underpaying workers – wage theft – are far smaller than the penalties individuals face for theft of items of equivalent value. Shoplifting goods worth $2,500 or more can lead to felony charges and imprisonment in every state (Traub 2017). Over 2005-2020, the DOL found more than 16,000 cases of minimum wage underpayment, and more than 76,000 cases of overtime underpayment, worth more than $2,500. The total value underpaid to workers across these was nearly $570 million. In this time there were 26 criminal convictions, 3 criminal fines, and no prison sentences for FLSA violations.

My work focuses on the expected penalties levied by the legal system, and excludes reputation costs. Enforcement agencies can and do leverage companies’ reputation concerns to incentivize compliance, over and above penalties (Ji and Weil 2015, Johnson 2020). But it is insufficient for a law to rely only on reputation: if so, workers at unscrupulous companies suffer, and ethical companies are at a competitive disadvantage.

Effective deterrence will only become more important as the federal minimum wage is increased. In real terms, the federal minimum wage is at its lowest level in 66 years (Cooper et al 2022) and, as a result, it applies to relatively few workers. If it was raised to $15, as per recent proposals, an estimated one in six US workers would be affected (Zipperer 2023) – with a correspondingly greater noncompliance problem (Clemens and Strain 2024).

_________

  1. See, for example, the 2021 Raise the Wage Act: https://www.help.senate.gov/ranking/newsroom/press/top-democrats-introduce-bill-raising-minimum-wage-to-15-by-2025.
  2. A survey of front-line workers in low-wage industries in Chicago, Los Angeles and New York found that 68% experienced at least one pay-related violation of federal or state law in any given week, at an average cost of 15% of wages (Bernhardt et al. 2009). Estimates using the Current Population Survey suggest variously that 2.4 million workers in the US’ ten most populous states are underpaid by an average of 25% of their weekly wages as a result of federal or state-level minimum wage violations (Cooper and Kroeger 2017); that 560,000 workers in New York and California experienced a minimum wage violation in any given week in 2011, with losses amounting to 37%-49% of worker income (Eastern Research Group 2014); and that 16.9% of low-wage workers across the US experienced a minimum wage violation in 2013, losing on average 23% of their earnings (Galvin 2016).
  3. The other DOL scenarios deal either with repeat violators, which are only 9% of all violators, or with upper bound estimates. The upper bound estimates look at the 95th percentile penalty for willful violators, separately for first-time and repeat violations.

See original post for references

Print Friendly, PDF & Email

18 comments

  1. Tommy S

    Is this backwards? I rarely question you or Lambert etc….but the purchasing power of $7,20 an hour is reversed isn’t it? I understand the inflation calculator, but that is for cost of goods, I don’t see how that can reflect increased purchasing power of a stagnant wage. ??

    Reply
  2. ScottB

    Yves, I believe you used the CPI calculator in the wrong direction. $7.25 per hour in 2009 is the equivalent of $4.92 per hour in 2024.

    Reply
    1. Fuzzy guy

      No, I think Yves was saying $7.25 in 2009 dollars would be ~$10 of buying power today. She then qualified it by pointing out that CPI understates reduction in buying power.

      Reply
  3. ProNewerDeal

    Thanks for this article.

    I feel there are many topics NOT covered in high school, that should be.

    I feel Bookeeping/Accounting 101 should be a required or promoted/suggested elective course, just on the point of view of reconciling the timecard with the W2 or 1099 pdf weekly paystub. Explain what the marginal Fed income tax, FICA, and state income deductions are. I feel it is good practice to be in the habit of checking this, regardless of worker or 1099-contractor, and PT fast food-type low prestige to FT physician-type high prestige worker. Wage theft can occur on undercounting hours and/or pay rate per hour. Explain a method to reconcile it. If wage-thefted, explain a process is to attempt getting un-robbed, eg “show your math work” to the Supervisor or HR, and if that fails, how to file a case with the state Labor Dept.

    A side benefit – for the portion of high school students that dislike math, this may motivate them to increase their math interest.

    Of course cue the Late Great George Carlin rant about The Murican Owners do not want us 99%ers being educated enough to think critically, even at this basic simple level.

    However, on the other hand, where is the Jaime Escalante-type passionate skilled teacher with a consumer advocate-Clark Howard type mindset in this accounting/personal finance speciality, advocating for this? If such Murican teacher(s) exist, I am unaware of them.

    Reply
  4. Yaiyen

    The thing i don’t understand if usa would have m4a, free education and a government who build affordable apartments to rent, people wouldn’t need such a high minimum wage. So why small business dont push for these more. It wouldn’t hurt them at all, they would save money in the longterm , they could even compete better against big business who can afford to pay people health care premiums

    Reply
    1. JBird4049

      One of the issues is the belief that too many people will be free riders mooching off public money. Really, the idea that anyone at all could be getting away with anything drives some people insane. That purchasing power of wages for the bottom half of the population has been declining for forty years with the decline working its way up the classes is also something that many people do not want to even accept as that means that the system needs reform.

      Then there is the American caste system, which has been in existence since the first European colonies or over four centuries, and is not acknowledged, nor is the joy or happiness (and I this is a deliberate word choice) lording over the inferior peasants. Although neither racism or eugenics are an American creation, the main, usually wealthy, supporters have mostly been American. Meaning that the worth of an individual by the system is how much money they have. Restated: If you are poor, please, go away and die. You don’t deserve to live. Hillary Clinton’s Deplorables.

      And since the government has been captured by wealthy families and corporations who not only feel that this is the truth and because they don’t want to share the money, they ain’t going to pay for the housing, healthcare, and education.

      It is not good, but it is true, I think.

      Reply
      1. Hepativore

        It also depends on the market sector. Retail, hospitality, and manufacturing sectors would probably like not having to have to provide things like health plans and retirement benefits which is why they often have mechanisms to dispose of workers who are in danger of qualifying for those benefits that employers supposedly offer.

        However, the FIRE sector that is involved in the financialization of healthcare, retirement programs, and other services is a lot more powerful than the firms in the above sectors so their influence holds more sway over our politicians.

        Also, employers like having the ability to use health insurance coverage and retirement plans as a bargaining chip to keep workers on their toes and encourage obedience, as losing your job also means losing their healthcare to most people and employers know and take advantage of this.

        I would not be surprised if our corporate overlords successfully lobby the Supreme Court to outlaw unions very soon at the rate things are going.

        Reply
    2. Paul Art

      I think it is the perennial interest group disease that has always ravaged the USA. Cannot go against the FIRE sector. The Democratic party must completely die before any meaningful change can occur. I heard Jimmy Dore do an interesting take on our situation. He said we are becoming like Brazil where there is no middle class, only the very rich and very poor. I agree with this and I think it’s happening in slow motion. I am expecting the Dems to dump the minimum wage issue from their platform altogether soon.

      Reply
  5. Oldtimer

    No need to comply, no one is working under $30/hour here in SoCal, if you can find one.
    People don’t realize how bad things are. Plumbers and electricians are charging close to $500/hour plus $120 trucking fee if you find one to show up.
    We needed to replace a 600amps electric panel in one of our multi family apartment buildings, got 7 estimates, the cheapest is $19,000 and 52 weeks waiting time to get the panel plus clause in the contract regarding the final price of the panel given the long delays. Same job 5 years ago cost us $4,800 and will be done within a week.
    Lots of work being cancelled for lack of materials and labor, it’s insane.

    Reply
  6. LarryMotuz

    So, introduce a major incentive for workers to report. Like 100 times the lost wages.

    And treat all failures to pay the minimum as purposeful*, with fines up to 1000 times earnings lost by all workers affected by the failure to pay those wages.

    *Ignorance of the law is no excuse given the Internet and the reality that we now live in an Information Economy.

    Reply
  7. Felix_47

    Exterminators are charging about 500 per hour as well. Of course the licensing requirements and workers comp requirements and insurance requirements are really high in CA. Any construction project is going to cost a ton. So it is somewhat understandable…..you are paying for a lot of things you do not see.

    Reply
  8. Phil R

    If Boston Dynamics has it’s way, there will be little need for a minimum wage:

    https://bostondynamics.com/blog/electric-new-era-for-atlas/

    “Our new electric Atlas platform is here. Supported by decades of visionary robotics innovation and years of practical experience, Boston Dynamics is tackling the next commercial frontier.

    The next generation of the Atlas program builds on decades of research and furthers our commitment to delivering the most capable, useful mobile robots solving the toughest challenges in industry today: with Spot, with Stretch, and now with Atlas.”

    and:

    “Traditionally, we have focused on legged robots because we wanted to build robots that could balance and move dynamically—robots that could navigate unstructured, unknown, or antagonistic terrain with ease. The humanoid form factor is a useful design for robots working in a world designed for people.”

    Think I, Robot.

    Reply

Leave a Reply

Your email address will not be published. Required fields are marked *